« December 2004 »
S M T W T F S
1 2 3 4
5 6 7 8 9 10 11
12 13 14 15 16 17 18
19 20 21 22 23 24 25
26 27 28 29 30 31
You are not logged in. Log in
Entries by Topic
All topics  «
Blog Tools
Edit your Blog
Build a Blog
View Profile
a list of links from Iraq
Iraq Blogcount
Lewyn Addresses America
Monday, 27 December 2004
Utah article on growth boundaries
2002 Utah L. Rev. 1


Utah Law Review
2002


Articles


*1 SPRAWL, GROWTH BOUNDARIES AND THE REHNQUIST COURT


Michael Lewyn [FNa1]


Copyright ? 2002 Utah Law Review Society; Michael Lewyn


I. Introduction
Over the past several decades, metropolitan America has been revolutionized by suburban sprawl--"low-density, single-use development, married with strip and auto-oriented commercial land uses, at the very edges or beyond the fringe of existing urbanization." [FN1] Sprawl typically involves: (1) low-density development requiring dependence on automobiles; (2) segregated land uses (that is, commercial uses are far from residential uses); (3) long distances and poor non-automotive access between housing, jobs, and schools; (4) consumption of land for suburban development occurring at a faster rate than population growth; and (5) "consumption of agricultural and/or environmentally sensitive land for suburban development." [FN2] At the end of World War II, roughly 70% of metropolitan Americans lived in central cities. [FN3] By contrast, in 1990, only about 40% of metropolitan Americans, and only 31.3% of all Americans, lived in central cities. [FN4] *2 In recent years environmentalists, [FN5] many planners, [FN6] and a few politicians [FN7] have sought to limit suburban sprawl. A recent survey by the General Accounting Office (GAO) revealed that 84% of county officials and 64% of city officials rate sprawl as a "high," "very high," or "moderate" concern. [FN8]
Critics of the status quo argue, inter alia, [FN9] that suburban sprawl:
1. Destabilizes urban neighborhoods, causing "a middle class exodus from the central city, causing in turn crime and the segregation of poorer and minority populations in the declining central city." [FN10]
2. Destroys farmland and open space; for example, "from 1982 to 1992 [America] lost to urban and suburban development an average of 400,000 acres per year of 'prime' farmland, the land with the best soils and climate for growing crops." [FN11]; and
*3 3. Forces Americans to drive in order to meet their basic needs, increasing vehicle traffic, thus increasing air pollution [FN12] and traffic congestion. [FN13]
*4 The most stringent [FN14] anti-sprawl measure adopted by any American state is Oregon's "urban growth boundary" (UGB) [FN15] program. Urban growth boundaries are "lines on maps, surrounding areas already marked by 'urban-type' development, within which that type of development is to be channeled and encouraged, *5 and beyond which such development is to be discouraged or forbidden." [FN16] Outside the boundary, rural industries (such as logging) and open space are promoted. [FN17]
This Article briefly describes Oregon law, and then focuses on three issues: (1) whether UGBs are constitutional under the Supreme Court's 2001 decision in Palazzolo v. Rhode Island [FN18] and other relevant precedent, (2) whether the UGB has in fact saved Portland (Oregon's largest city) [FN19] from the social problems caused by sprawl, and (3) whether the side effects of UGBs make them a cure worse than the disease of sprawl.


II. Background: What Oregon Law Requires
In 1973, Oregon enacted Senate Bill 100, which established a comprehensive statewide growth management program. [FN20] Senate Bill 100 was enacted based on legislative findings that "[u]ncoordinated use of lands within this state threaten the orderly development, the environment of this state and the health, safety, order, convenience, prosperity and welfare of the people of this state," [FN21] and that "[t]he promotion of coordinated statewide land conservation and development requires the creation of a statewide planning agency to prescribe planning goals and objectives to be applied by state agencies, cities, counties and special districts *6 throughout the state." [FN22] The Oregon Legislature accordingly created a new citizen commission to oversee the planning program, the Land Conservation and Development Commission (LCDC). [FN23] The Legislature also created the Department of Land Conservation and Development as LCDC's staff for implementing the program, [FN24] and directed the LCDC to appoint the Department's director and supervise its staff. [FN25] The Legislature further required all Oregon cities and counties to adopt comprehensive land use plans and regulations implementing such plans. [FN26] The Legislature defined a comprehensive plan as a "generalized, coordinated land use map and policy statement . . . that interrelates all functional and natural systems and activities relating to the use of lands, including but not limited to sewer and water systems, transportation systems, educational facilities, recreational facilities, and natural resources and air and water quality management programs." [FN27] Such plans must be consistent with statewide planning goals [FN28] to be drafted by the LCDC. [FN29] Between 1974 and 1976, the LCDC adopted nineteen planning goals. [FN30] Local governments then adopted land use plans, which were reviewed by LCDC. [FN31]
Although the Oregon Legislature did not directly state that local governments must establish UGBs, it implicitly did so by using the term "urban growth boundary" in numerous statutes. [FN32] So the LCDC satisfied legislative intent when *7 it enacted Planning Goal 14, which specifically requires every incorporated community to establish a UGB [FN33] that excludes rural land. [FN34] The Oregon courts have interpreted Goal 14 "to prohibit urbanization outside existing UGBs" [FN35] and therefore to "preclud[e] the conversion of rural land to urban use" [FN36] outside UGBs. [FN37] Neither Goal 14 nor any other LCDC rule defines the term "urban use." [FN38] However, the Oregon courts have held that an outdoor performing arts center seating 15,000 people is an "urban" [FN39] land use, as are "areas of half-acre residential lots to be served by community water and sewer." [FN40] On the other hand, "residential density of one house per ten acres is generally not an urban intensity." [FN41]
Land outside UGBs may be converted to "urban use" only if such land is physically developed to the extent that it is no longer available for rural land uses [FN42] or is "irrevocably committed to urban levels of development" [FN43]--that is, if "it is impracticable to allow any rural uses in the . . . area." [FN44] To take advantage of these exceptions to Goal 14 (or to "take an exception," in the terminology used by Oregon courts), [FN45] a local government must show not only that commercial farm or forest use is impractical, but that all other rural uses (including sparse settlement, small farms, etc.) are impractical. [FN46]
*8 A UGB must contain the urban core and sufficient undeveloped land to accommodate population growth. [FN47] UGBs are drawn and amended based on seven factors enunciated in Goal 14: (1) the need to accommodate long-term population growth consistent with LCDC goals, (2) the need for housing, employment opportunities, and livability, (3) the orderly and economic provision for public facilities and services, (4) maximum efficiency of land uses, (5) the environmental, energy, economic, and social consequences of a plan, (6) the retention of agricultural land uses, and (7) the compatibility of urban land uses with nearby agricultural activities. [FN48]
Portland's UGB is administered by a regional agency, the Portland Metropolitan Service District (commonly known as "Metro"). [FN49] Metro has the power to force cities and counties to amend their land use plans to conform with the boundary set by Metro. [FN50] The Portland metropolitan UGB was adopted by Metro in 1979, approved by LCDC in 1980, [FN51] and encompasses twenty-four municipalities, portions of three counties, [FN52] and 369 square miles (or 236,000 acres) of land. [FN53]


III. Constitutionality: Are UGBs an Unconstitutional "Taking" of Land?
The United States Constitution provides that private property may not "be taken for public use, without just compensation." [FN54] It is not clear that the Framers of the Takings Clause intended it to restrict regulation of property (as opposed to *9 actual physical appropriation). [FN55] Nevertheless, the Supreme Court has held that "there will be instances when government actions do not encroach upon or occupy the property yet still affect and limit its use to such an extent that a taking occurs." [FN56] Some commentators have suggested that UGBs are intrusive enough to constitute a "taking" of land, and thus cannot be implemented unless the government compensates all property owners adversely affected thereby. [FN57] Although no Supreme Court case is directly on point, lower court decisions have indirectly addressed the constitutionality of growth boundaries.

A. Are UGBs a "Taking" Under Supreme Court Precedent?


1. The Key Cases: A Summary
In the 1978 case of Penn Central Transportation Co. v. New York City, [FN58] the Supreme Court announced a three-part balancing test governing "regulatory takings" cases: in determining whether a land use regulation is intrusive enough to constitute a "taking," the court weighs the regulation's economic effect on the landowner, the extent to which the regulation interferes with a landowner's reasonable investment-backed expectations, and the character of the government action. [FN59] In the Palazzolo case, the Supreme Court reiterated its commitment to the Penn Central balancing test. [FN60]
*10 Of all the Court's post- Penn Central cases, the case of Agins v. Tiburon [FN61] is most closely on point. The Agins plaintiffs challenged municipal zoning ordinances that prohibited the construction of more than five single-family homes on the plaintiffs' five-acre tract of land. [FN62] Specifically, the plaintiffs argued that the zoning ordinances were a "taking" because they "forever prevented [their land's] development for residential use" [FN63] and thus "completely destroyed the [land's] value." [FN64]
The Supreme Court upheld the zoning ordinances, for two reasons. First, the ordinances "substantially advance legitimate governmental goals" [FN65]-- specifically, "protect[ing] the residents of [the city] from the ill effects of urbanization." [FN66] Second, the ordinances did not "prevent the best use of [plaintiffs'] land . . . nor extinguish a fundamental attribute of ownership" [FN67] because the plaintiffs "may be permitted to build as many as five houses on their five acres of prime residential property." [FN68]
The zoning ordinances upheld in Agins are quite similar to Oregon's urban growth boundaries. Both UGBs and the zoning laws at issue in Agins limit development in rural areas in order to prevent urbanization of those areas. [FN69] And like the ordinances at issue in Agins, Oregon law allows some residential development on rural land: the Oregon Supreme Court has stated that residential development outside UGBs is not an "urban use" (and is therefore allowed) if the developer builds no more than one unit every ten acres, [FN70] and has reserved judgment on whether the one-acre lots contemplated by Agins [FN71] are "urban" (and thus presumably forbidden outside UGBs). [FN72] In other words, the major difference *11 between the ordinances upheld in Agins and Oregon law is that the former allowed landowners to build one lot per acre, while Oregon law allows landowners to build one lot (and maybe more) per ten acres--a distinction of no obvious constitutional significance.
It could be argued that Agins is no longer dispositive, because Rehnquist Court rulings have sharply curtailed government regulation of land use. [FN73] Two decisions in particular are arguably relevant: Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council [FN74] and Palazzolo v. Rhode Island. [FN75]
The Lucas plaintiff purchased two beachfront lots in South Carolina on which he intended to build houses. [FN76] Two years after he purchased the lots, the state enacted a law which prohibited such beachfront construction. [FN77] The Court assumed for the purposes of its decision that this statute "rendered [plaintiff's] parcels 'valueless."' [FN78] The Court stated that as a general rule, [FN79] a taking occurs when land use regulation (1) "'does not substantially advance legitimate state *12 interests"' [FN80] or (2) "'denies an owner economically viable use of his land."' [FN81] Because the statute at issue prevented the plaintiff from gaining any financial benefit from his land, the Court held that the plaintiff had suffered a constitutional taking unless the state could "identify background principles of nuisance and property law that prohibit the uses he now intends." [FN82] The Court reasoned that
regulations that leave the owner of land without economically beneficial or productive options for its use--typically, as here, by requiring land to be left substantially in its natural state--carry with them a heightened risk that private property is being pressed into some form of public service under the guise of mitigating serious public harm. [FN83]
The Court accordingly remanded the case to the South Carolina courts so the state could have a chance to "identify background principles of nuisance and property law that prohibit the uses [Lucas] now intends in the circumstances in which the property is presently found." [FN84] The Court added in dicta that a landowner "whose deprivation is one step short of complete" [FN85] may be entitled to compensation under certain circumstances, explaining:
Such an owner might not be able to claim the benefit of our categorical formulation, but, as we have acknowledged time and again, '[t]he economic impact of the regulation on the claimant and . . . the extent to which the regulation has interfered with distinct investment-backed expectations' are keenly relevant to takings analysis generally. [FN86]
The Palazzolo court elaborated on Lucas by clarifying the Court's definition of a "total taking" [FN87] and by explaining the relationship among the factors relevant *13 to "partial taking" cases. [FN88] In 1959, the Palazzolo plaintiff formed a corporation to develop waterfront land in Rhode Island. [FN89] The corporation's applications were denied three times by various Rhode Island agencies--first for lack of essential information, and later on environmental grounds. [FN90] In 1971, Rhode Island enacted legislation creating the Rhode Island Coastal Resources Management Council ("the Council"), an administrative agency charged with the duty of protecting the state's wetlands. [FN91] In 1978, the corporation's charter was revoked for failure to pay corporate income taxes, and title to the property passed to the plaintiff as the corporation's sole shareholder. [FN92] The plaintiff then filed two additional development applications with the Council. Both were denied because of their adverse impact on salt marshes within the property; [FN93] under the Council's regulations, such salt marshes were "coastal wetlands" on which development must be limited. [FN94] The Rhode Island Supreme Court affirmed the decision of the Council. [FN95] The plaintiff appealed this decision to the U.S. Supreme Court, which reversed in part and remanded. [FN96]
The Supreme Court began its opinion with a general description of the law of regulatory takings. The Court held that "a regulation which 'denies all economically beneficial or productive use of the land' will require compensation under the Takings Clause." [FN97] The Court added that
where a regulation places limitations on land that fall short of eliminating all economically beneficial use, a taking nonetheless may have occurred, depending on a complex of facts including the regulation's economic effect on the landowner, the extent to which the regulation interferes with reasonable investment-backed expectations, and the character of the government action. [FN98] *14 Thus, the government generally must compensate landowners for regulations that are "total takings," [FN99] that is, those that deprive landowners of all "economically beneficial use" of their land. [FN100] By contrast, "partial taking[s]," [FN101] that is, regulations that do not eliminate all economically beneficial use of the plaintiff's land, are judged by the Penn Central three-part balancing test. [FN102]
As to the "total takings" half of this test, the Court affirmed the Rhode Island court, holding that the Rhode Island regulations were not a "total taking" because even after the Rhode Island authorities' adverse decision, the plaintiff could still build a $200,000 residence on his eighteen-acre parcel. [FN103] The Court explained that "[a] regulation permitting a landowner to build a substantial residence on an 18-acre parcel does not leave the property 'economically idle."' [FN104] Further, "it is undisputed that the parcel retains significant worth for construction of a residence." [FN105]
The Court went on, however, to hold that the Rhode Island Supreme Court had erroneously analyzed the plaintiff's "partial takings" claim, and to remand the case to the Rhode Island courts so that they could address that claim under the Penn Central balancing test. [FN106] The Court reversed for two reasons. First, the Rhode Island Supreme Court erred in holding that the plaintiff's takings claim was not yet ripe for judicial review. [FN107] Second, the state court erred in holding that the plaintiff "had no reasonable investment-backed expectations that were affected by [the state's] regulation . . . [because he] did not become the owner of the land until 1978 . . . [when] there were already regulations in place limiting Palazzolo's ability to fill the wetlands for development." [FN108]
As to the latter issue, the Court explained that an otherwise unreasonable taking
do[es] not become less so through passage of time or title. . . . [Otherwise] the post enactment transfer of title would absolve the State of its obligation to defend any action restricting land use, no matter how extreme or unreasonable. A State would be allowed, in effect, to put an expiration date on the Takings Clause. [FN109] *15 In other words, a regulation may be a compensable "taking" even if it is enacted before the plaintiff buys the land being "taken."
Because the Court so held by a five to four margin, [FN110] Justice O'Connor's separate concurrence is especially significant as to the "investment-backed expectations" issue. Justice O'Connor wrote that "the Rhode Island Supreme Court erred in effectively adopting the sweeping rule that the preacquisition enactment of the use restriction ipso facto defeats any takings claim based on that use restriction," but that nonetheless, the Court's holding "[did] not mean that the timing of the regulation's enactment relative to the acquisition of title is immaterial to the Penn Central analysis." [FN111] Instead, "interference with investment-backed expectations is one of a number of factors that a court must examine. . . . [T]he regulatory regime in place at the time the claimant acquires the property at issue helps shape the reasonableness of those expectations." [FN112] In support of this view, Justice O'Connor reasoned that if
existing regulations dictate the reasonableness of [investment-backed] expectations in every instance, then the State wields far too much power to redefine property rights upon passage of title. . . . [But] if existing regulations do nothing to inform the analysis, then some property owners may reap windfalls and an important indicium of fairness is lost. [FN113] Justice O'Connor accordingly wrote that rather than adopting "per se rules," [FN114] courts "must attend to those circumstances which are probative of what fairness requires in a given case." [FN115] In other words, "investment-backed expectations" are *16 one of the three factors examined under the Penn Central balancing test, and a landowner's decision to acquire property already governed by the challenged regulations is in turn highly relevant to the presence or absence of such expectations.
Justice O'Connor also discussed the third of the Penn Central factors: the "character of the governmental action" challenged by a Takings Clause plaintiff. [FN116] She explained that under this prong of the Penn Central test, a "use restriction on real property may constitute a 'taking' if not reasonably necessary to the effectuation of a substantial public purpose." [FN117] This language echoes the Agins Court's requirement that a regulation "substantially advance legitimate governmental goals" [FN118] in order to not constitute a taking. Because Justice O'Connor supplied the crucial fifth vote for the Court's decision, her concurrence is likely to be followed by future courts. [FN119]
In sum, Palazzolo, interpreted in light of Justice O'Connor's concurrence holds:
1. That "a regulation which 'denies all economically beneficial or productive use of land' will require compensation under the Takings Clause." [FN120]
2. That a regulation allowing a landowner to build one house on eighteen acres of land is not such a "total" taking. [FN121]
3. That regulations other than "total takings" are governed by the Penn Central balancing test, under which the courts must balance: (a) "the regulation's economic effect on the landowner," [FN122] (b) "the extent to which the regulation interferes with reasonable investment-backed expectations," [FN123] and (c) "the character of the government action" [FN124] (that is, the extent to which a "substantial public purpose" [FN125] supports the regulation at issue).
*17 2. Applying the Case Law to UGBs


(a) Are UGBs an Unconstitutional "Total Taking"?
As noted above, a regulation which "denies all economically beneficial or productive use of land" [FN126] will generally require compensation under the Takings Clause. UGB statutes modeled on Oregon law are clearly not such a "total taking" under Palazzolo. [FN127] The Palazzolo plaintiff sought to persuade the Supreme Court that he suffered a "total taking" [FN128] because he could only build one $200,000 residence on his eighteen-acre parcel. [FN129] The Supreme Court flatly rejected this theory, holding that a regulation "permitting a landowner to build a substantial residence on an eighteen-acre parcel does not leave the property 'economically idle."' [FN130]
Landowners in Oregon can do far more with their land than the Palazzolo plaintiff could do with his, for two reasons. First, the Oregon courts have held that houses on ten-acre lots are not "urban uses" [FN131] and thus may be built outside UGBs. [FN132] By contrast, the Palazzolo plaintiff could only build one house on an eighteen-acre parcel. [FN133] Second, Oregon landowners are not even limited to building one house on a large parcel of land: instead, they may also use land outside UGBs for agricultural purposes, [FN134] and may even convert such land to urban uses if "it is impracticable to allow any rural uses" [FN135] on such land. Thus, Oregon law is apparently less restrictive than the regulations challenged in Palazzolo. It follows that if the Rhode Island regulations at issue in Palazzolo did not "leave the [plaintiff's] property 'economically idle,"' [FN136] Oregon's less *18 restrictive laws do not do so either, and thus are not a "total taking" under Lucas and Palazzolo.
Some commentators endorse a more pro-plaintiff interpretation of Supreme Court precedent. For example, one commentator writes that because UGBs "prevent development consistent with the otherwise predictable use of the property," [FN137] they automatically deprive landowners of "all or mostly all of the value of their property." [FN138] But this need not be the case. For example, suppose that a zoning ordinance, by preventing Blackacre from being turned into a subdivision, reduces its fair market value [FN139] from $20 per square foot to $12 per square foot. Blackacre will have lost 40% of its value--more than the owners would like, but certainly less than "all or mostly all of the value of their property." [FN140] By contrast, in Lucas, the value of plaintiff's property was allegedly reduced to zero. [FN141]
It has also been suggested that a taking occurs whenever property suffers "a significant dimunition in value." [FN142] If this is the case, UGBs, although not per se unconstitutional, [FN143] may lead to a large number of successful takings claims, because
the creation of the boundary itself will cause dramatic differences between the value of undeveloped property inside the boundary and the value of similar property outside. . . . [T]hose on the inside can rest assured that the supply of developable land is now artificially limited, and hence more valuable. Those on the outside will be prohibited from entering the market. [FN144] *19 The "significant dimunition in value" standard, however, was rejected in both Lucas and Palazzolo. The Lucas Court held that "in at least some cases the landowner with 95% loss will get nothing." [FN145] Moreover, a year after Lucas, the Supreme Court cited cases rejecting challenges to regulations that diminished land value by 75% and 92.5%, in a decision unanimously reaffirming that "our cases have long established that mere diminution in the value of property, however serious, is insufficient to demonstrate a taking." [FN146] As a result of such statements, lower courts applying Lucas have "not usually found a taking because the land use regulation attacked did not deny the landowner all economically viable use." [FN147]
The Palazzolo Court similarly held that a regulation that "places limitations on land that fall short of eliminating all economically beneficial use" [FN148] is not automatically invalid, but rather is subject to the Penn Central balancing test. [FN149] Thus, a regulation that significantly reduces the value of a landowner's property is not per se unconstitutional.


(b) Applying the Penn Central Balancing Test to UGBs
As explained above, [FN150] even a "partial taking" (that is, one that reduces the value of a landowner's property by less than 100%) may be a compensable regulatory taking if it "interferes with reasonable investment-backed expectations" [FN151] or is not "reasonably necessary to the effectuation of a substantial public purpose." [FN152] Neither of these factors turns Oregon's UGB statutes into a compensable "taking."
i. Investment-Backed Expectations
Justice O'Connor, writing as the crucial fifth vote in support of a five to four decision, [FN153] wrote that "the state of regulatory affairs at the time of acquisition" [FN154] *20 is relevant to the extent of landowners' investment-backed expectations, and that "the nature and extent of the permitted development under the regulatory regime vis-a-vis the development sought by the landowner may also shape legitimate expectations." [FN155] It follows that a UGB is unlikely to interfere with landowners' investment-backed expectations where, as in Oregon, UGBs have existed for over two decades, [FN156] because a property owner will rarely have an "investment-backed expectation" in resisting enforcement of statewide statutes and regulations enacted decades ago. [FN157]
Even in states where UGBs have not yet been enacted, proposed UGBs are likely to interfere with a landowner's reasonable investment-backed expectations only if a landowner reasonably relied on their absence--for example, where property outside the UGB has previously been zoned for (or was about to be zoned for) intensive development, and a landowner bought the property in reliance upon such zoning. [FN158] Otherwise, the landowner's reasonable expectations will not have been affected by the newly enacted UGB. State and local governments can easily minimize such problems by including land already zoned for development within UGBs. [FN159] It therefore appears that even if UGBs do diminish rural property values, rural landowners will rarely have constitutional claims under Supreme Court precedent.


ii. Substantial Public Purpose
Finally, a "partial taking" may also be a compensable taking if it is not supported by a "substantial public purpose." [FN160] As noted above, the Agins court held that limiting the spread of urbanization is a legitimate state interest justifying restrictions upon development of rural and suburban land. [FN161] Thus, UGBs (which, in Oregon, were enacted at least partially in order to protect rural land from the *21 spread of suburbia) [FN162] are clearly supported by a "substantial public purpose" under Agins.
In sum, three factors are relevant to whether a land use regulation constitutes a taking: the weight of the state interests favoring the regulation; whether the regulation renders plaintiff's property valueless or nearly so; and whether the regulation interferes with plaintiff's reasonable investment-backed expectations. [FN163] None of these factors supports a finding that UGBs generally constitute a "taking" that requires governments to compensate adversely affected landowners. Thus, UGBs are constitutional under Rehnquist Court case law.

B. Lower Courts Address UGBs (Sort Of)
Although the Oregon courts have upheld Oregon's land use laws, [FN164] they have never specifically addressed the constitutionality of UGBs. However, one federal decision indirectly supports the constitutionality of UGBs. In Buckles v. King County, [FN165] plaintiffs challenged a county's decision to zone their property as "Rural Area" pursuant to the Washington growth management statute (which established "urban growth areas" similar to the Oregon UGBs). [FN166] Plaintiffs *22 argued, inter alia, that this "designation 'fails to advance a legitimate county interest and thereby takes Plaintiffs' property without payment of just compensation."' [FN167]
The U.S. Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit began its discussion by noting that, as a general rule, "a land use regulation does not constitute a taking if the regulation does not deny a landowner all economically viable use of the property and if the regulation substantially advances a legitimate government interest." [FN168] The court then held that the county had advanced numerous substantial interests in support of its decision, one of which was "complying with the Growth Management Act's limitation on urban development outside of the urban growth boundary because the [plaintiffs'] property lies outside of King County's urban growth boundary." [FN169] If "limitation on urban development outside of the urban growth boundary" is a legitimate state interest, it arguably follows that a UGB statute specifically designed to limit such development advances a legitimate state interest. Thus, Buckles supports the constitutionality of UGBs.


IV. Have UGBs Cured the Mischiefs of Sprawl?
Although UGBs are probably constitutional, they may nevertheless be unwise if they fail to prevent problems associated with sprawl, such as urban decay, destruction of farmland, and automobile dependency. Oregon's UGBs appear to have prevented the urban decay that other cities have suffered as a result of sprawl. However, the impact of the UGB upon the Portland region's land use and transportation patterns has been less dramatic.

A. Saving the City
As suburbs have grown, older central cities throughout America have emptied out. Between 1900 and 1950, every large American city gained *23 population. [FN170] But most older cities have been devastated by sprawl: of the eighteen American cities with over 500,000 people in 1950, thirteen lost population in the 1950s, fifteen in the 1960s, and sixteen in the 1970s. [FN171] For example, by 2000 St. Louis had lost almost 60% of its 1950 population, while Buffalo and Cleveland had lost nearly half of their 1950 population. [FN172] Those cities that have gained population have done so either by becoming hubs for foreign immigration or by annexing newly developed areas that would be considered suburbs in other cities. [FN173] As cities have become smaller, they have become poorer. In 1990, thirty-one of America's thirty-seven largest cities had poverty rates above the national average, [FN174] and central cities contained half of America's poor (as opposed to one-third in 1960). [FN175] Jobs, as well as people, have fled to suburbia: about 95% of the fifteen million new jobs created in the 1980s were in suburbs. [FN176]
In some regions, city life is not a viable choice for any residents other than the poorest or most adventurous. For example, only 4% of Cleveland-area households earning over $100,000 live in the city of Cleveland. [FN177] Even institutions that would be urban in other communities are suburban in Cleveland: the office of EcoCity Cleveland, one of the area's leading anti-sprawl groups, is located in the suburb of Cleveland Heights. [FN178]
Middle-class flight feeds upon itself: as cities become more and more dominated by the poor, who cannot afford to move to suburbia, city neighborhoods become more dangerous (because poverty-packed areas have higher crime *24 rates), [FN179] city schools become less prestigious (because children from poor backgrounds are typically less academically proficient than students from affluent backgrounds), [FN180] and city tax bases dwindle due to the city's poverty (thus causing higher taxes and inadequate services) [FN181]--thus causing additional middle-class flight. [FN182]
While some older cities have decayed, Portland has grown and prospered. From 1980 (when the Portland UGB was created) [FN183] to 2000, the city of Portland's population grew by over 40% [FN184] after declining for several decades. [FN185] Moreover, Portland's population growth compared favorably to that of the central cities of the most comparable western metropolitan areas. Table 1 compares Portland's growth to that of Denver, Salt Lake City, and Seattle--three regions *25 that, although otherwise comparable, [FN186] have lacked UGBs for most or all of the past two decades. [FN187]


*26 TABLE 1: POPULATION GROWTH

City population % Metropolitan area
increase/decrease population % increase
1950-80 [FN188] 1980-2000 1980-2000 [FN190]
[FN189]
Portland -1.5 43.7 43.8
Denver 18.4 12.3 47.5
Seattle 5.6 14.0 46.2
Salt Lake 10.4 11.0 46.5
City

As Table 1 shows, the UGB allowed Portland to gain a proportionate share of the region's population growth, while Denver, Seattle, and Salt Lake City were left in the dust by their suburbs. By contrast, in the decades before the UGB was adopted, Portland was losing population while Denver and Seattle gained population--even though Portland annexed thirty-nine miles of land between 1950 and 1980, increasing its land mass by nearly 60%. [FN191]
Moreover, Denver, Seattle, and Salt Lake City are far healthier than some other cities in high-growth regions. For example, the Atlanta metropolitan area's population grew by over 80% (far faster than metropolitan Portland) during the 1980s and 1990s [FN192]--yet while the Atlanta region's population surged, Atlanta's central city population actually declined from 425,000 to just over 416,000. [FN193] *27 Similarly, metropolitan Washington, D.C. grew by over 40% from 1980 to 2000 [FN194] while the central city population tumbled from 638,000 to just over 572,000. [FN195]
Because Portland annexed almost twenty-two miles of previously suburban territory in the 1980s, [FN196] it could be argued that annexation rather than UGBs caused Portland's startling growth. This argument is probably incorrect, for two reasons. First, as Table 2 shows, Salt Lake City and Denver annexed even more territory than Portland did, yet they failed to experience comparable urban growth.


TABLE 2: CENTRAL CITY GROWTH THROUGH ANNEXATION, 1980-1990

% increase in city land area % increase in population
[FN197] [FN198]
Portland 21.0 43.7
Seattle 0 12.3
Denver 37.7 14.0
Salt Lake City 47.7 11.0

Second, Portland annexed land during the 1950s, 1960s, and 1970s just as it did in the 1980s, yet failed to gain population because the city's land area failed to keep up with the migration of city residents to suburbia: Portland encompassed 64 square miles in 1950 and 103 square miles in 1980--yet the city *28 actually lost population. [FN199] Without UGBs to limit sprawl, Oregonians moved to suburbia faster than the city of Portland could expand its boundaries. [FN200]
As Portland's population has grown, its economy has grown as well. The number of private sector jobs increased by 21.4% in the city of Portland between 1992 and 1997 [FN201] while jobs in Salt Lake City, Denver, and Seattle increased by 6.6%, 8.8%, and 8.4% respectively. [FN202]
Because of Portland's growth and prosperity, Portland is one of the few central cities that has not become a dumping ground for the region's poor. Table 3 compares poverty trends in Portland and other western cities to poverty trends in their suburbs.


*29 TABLE 3: POVERTY TRENDS, 1979-97 [FN203]

Poverty rate [FN204] 1979 Poverty rate 1997
Denver City 13.7 16.4
Denver suburbs 5.4 6.5
Seattle City 11.2 12.9
Seattle suburbs 6.1 5.9
Salt Lake City 14.2 16.2
Salt Lake City suburbs 6.3 6.7
Portland City 13.0 12.6
Portland suburbs 7.2 7.8

In Denver, Seattle, and Salt Lake City, the central city poverty rate is more than twice the suburban poverty rate, and the gap between city and suburb has stayed roughly the same or grown. [FN205] By contrast, Portland has actually narrowed the city-suburb economic gap: its poverty rate was 1.8 times the suburban poverty rate in 1979, and was only 1.61 times the suburban poverty rate in 1997. [FN206]
In sum, Portland's UGB has arguably enhanced rather than reduced consumer choice, by making the city of Portland a viable option for middle-class households. Before the UGB was created in the 1980s, Portland was losing population while other western cities were gaining population. But over the past two decades, Portland has (unlike other western cities) grown as fast as its suburbs, and has narrowed the city-suburb economic gap. So for city- dwellers and would-be city-dwellers, the UGB has been a success on this ground alone.

B. Protection of Natural Resources
The preservation of agricultural and other natural resources areas was a *30 primary motivation behind Oregon's planning statutes. [FN207] For example, Oregon law justifies the creation of LCDC by stating that the "promotion of coordinated statewide land conservation and development requires the creation of a statewide planning agency." [FN208] Presumably, the UGB's success in this respect can be measured by Oregon's success in preserving farmland.
Table 4 shows the amount of farmland in the counties that are part of the Portland, Denver, Seattle, and Salt Lake City metro areas.


TABLE 4: ACRES OF FARMLAND IN METRO-AREA COUNTIES [FN209]

1987 1992 1997 [FN210] % loss 1987-97
Portland 605,201 571,588 596,903 1.4
Seattle 154,628 135,969 118,141 23.5
Salt Lake City 418,138 414,542 263,120 37.0
Denver 1,311,463 1,312,770 1,308,710 0.2

*31 Table 4 suggests that Oregon's policies have been only moderately successful at preserving rural land. The Portland region has slowed farmland loss, but one of the three comparable metro areas (Denver) has been slightly more successful in doing so. On the other hand, the Portland region actually gained agricultural land between 1992 and 1997, while Denver's progress in farmland preservation was reversed. Thus, it is too early to tell whether the UGB is increasing the supply of farmland and/or rural land.
The inconclusive results of the UGB were hardly unforeseeable, because at the time of its creation, the Portland UGB included some vacant buildable land, thereby allowing developers to urbanize rural land without running afoul of the UGB. [FN211] This "land cushion" constituted 37% of the buildable land within the UGB, [FN212] giving developers ample opportunity to urbanize inside the UGB land. Presumably, a stricter UGB would have reduced development of rural land, but might have created negative side effects (such as land shortages leading to higher housing prices). [FN213] Moreover, thousands of "exurban" houses have been built outside the UGB, either on lands zoned for commercial farm and forest production or on "exception lands" (that is, land outside the UGB but identified as "committed" to urban land uses). [FN214] Thus, the UGB was lenient enough to allow development of a significant amount of rural land.
In sum, the Oregon UGB has been at best moderately successful in slowing the urbanization of rural areas: metropolitan Portland lost farmland in the 1980s and early 1990s, but may have slowed or halted those losses in recent years.

C. Sprawl, Automobile Dependency, and Portland
Thanks in part to suburban sprawl, [FN215] Americans drive more than ever. Between 1983 and 1995, the length of the average American commute increased by 37%. [FN216] As a result, vehicle miles traveled (VMT) grew four times faster than the driving-age population, as Americans spread farther and farther apart. [FN217] Also, because more Americans than ever live far from bus stops and other transit *32 facilities, [FN218] public transit usage in the U.S. is far lower than in other affluent countries, [FN219] and many jobs are simply inaccessible to the carless urban poor. [FN220] By making automobile ownership virtually mandatory for a normal life, [FN221] sprawl limits consumers' transportation choices [FN222] while arguably increasing traffic congestion [FN223] and air pollution. [FN224]
One measure of automobile dependency is the growth or decline of public transit use. Table 5 addresses this issue.


*33 TABLE 5: ANNUAL TRANSIT BOARDINGS, 1980-96 (IN MILLIONS) [FN225]

1980 boardings 1996 boardings % increase
Denver 46.9 69.8 48.7
Portland 50.3 79.8 58.7
Salt Lake City 19.1 23.8 24.9
Seattle 98.2 115.5 17.6

All four metropolitan areas experienced increased transit ridership at a time when the majority of metropolitan transit systems actually lost riders [FN226]--but transit ridership grew faster in Portland than in Denver, Seattle, or Salt Lake City. Because cities tend to be more transit-accessible than suburbs, [FN227] UGB-related growth in city population [FN228] may have contributed to Portland's surge in transit ridership.
It does not appear, however, that automobile use has decreased in Portland. Table 6 compares vehicle miles traveled ("VMT") in Portland to VMT in other urbanized areas.


*34 TABLE 6: DAILY VMT PER CAPITA IN URBANIZED AREAS, 1989-99 [FN229]

1989 1999 % increase
Denver 17.3 23.2 34.1
Portland 18.9 20.8 10.0
Salt Lake City 18.5 22.6 22.1
Seattle 24.2 25.9 7.0

Table 6 shows that Portlanders drive less than other westerners, and that their per capita VMT has grown more slowly than that of Salt Lake City and Denver commuters. Table 6 also shows, however, that Portland's VMT has grown more quickly than that of Seattle commuters. Although city residents drive less than suburbanites, [FN230] the number of city residents arguably added by the UGB (161,000 if every single city resident added between 1980 and 2000 would have lived in the suburbs otherwise) [FN231] comprised only 8.3% of the region's population [FN232]--not enough to massively reduce automobile use, especially since most residents of the city of Portland drive to work. [FN233]
In sum, Portland's transportation patterns differ only modestly from those of its western neighbors: transit use has risen, but automobile use has risen as well (albeit more slowly than in some other metropolitan areas).


*35 V. Are UGBs a Cure Worse Than the Disease?
The case against the UGB has been stated succinctly by the Almanac of American Politics, an authoritative guide [FN234] to American politics:
[Portland's] 'livable community' comes at a price. The Portland area was recently rated the fourth-least affordable place in the nation to purchase a new home. Portland's policies guarantee greater traffic congestion; even optimistic planners acknowledge that its population growth will be much larger than the number of people who can be persuaded to use mass transit. Greater population densities produce more intense pollution . . . . [FN235] In other words, the Almanac suggests that the UGB: (1) reduces housing affordability by limiting development; and (2) creates traffic congestion and pollution by increasing density. Other commentators have suggested that the UGB reduces housing quality by increasing density, and that regardless of their beneficial effects, such land use controls are an inappropriate government intrusion into property rights. [FN236] Each of these arguments will be addressed in turn.

A. Portland's So-Called Affordability Crisis
By most measures, Portland is not one of America's most expensive metropolitan areas. According to the National Association of Home Builders (NAHB), Portland's median home sale price in 2000 was $168,000, far less than *36 San Francisco ($505,000), New York ($237,000), Seattle ($220,000), Denver ($183,000) and literally dozens of other metropolitan areas. [FN237]
It could be argued that even though Portland is not incredibly expensive, the UGB has nevertheless triggered an affordability crisis by creating a rapid increase in home prices. [FN238] Table 7 tests this theory by comparing Portland's housing price increases to those of comparable metropolitan areas.


TABLE 7: HOUSING PRICE INCREASES IN THE URBAN WEST, 1991-2000 [FN239]

1991 median price (in 2000 median price (in % increase
thousands of dollars) thousands of dollars)
(1st quarter) (3rd quarter)
Denver 84 183 117
Portland 80 168 110
Salt Lake 76 151 98
City
Seattle 130 220 69

Table 7 shows that home prices in Portland have increased more slowly than home prices in Denver, and that Portland-area housing price appreciation has been only slightly more rapid than price appreciation in other western regions.
It could be argued that despite Portland's perfectly ordinary rates of housing appreciation, Portland's houses are nevertheless relatively more expensive than houses in other regions because wages are lower in Portland. Table 8 sets forth the ratio between median income and median home price for Portland and comparable metropolitan areas.


*37 TABLE 8: MEDIAN INCOMES AND MEDIAN HOME PRICES, 2000 (in thousands of
dollars) [FN240]

Median income Median home price Income as % of home price
Denver 62.1 183 33.9
Portland 53.7 168 31.9
Salt Lake City 53.4 151 35.3
Seattle 65.8 220 29.9

Table 8 shows that even after Portland's lower wages are accounted for, Portland is more affordable than Seattle and only slightly less affordable than Denver or Salt Lake City. In all four areas, the median home price exceeds median income by about a three to one margin.
If Portland's housing appreciation rate is lower than Denver's and its overall prices are lower than Seattle's, then why is it so often argued that Portland is unaffordable? UGB critics rely on the NAHB Housing Opportunity Index (HOI) [FN241] which, in recent years, has consistently labeled Portland as one of the nation's most expensive metropolitan areas. [FN242] The HOI, however, yields preposterous results. For example, metropolitan New York City's median income is only $2500 higher than Portland's ($56,200 as opposed to Portland's $53,700), and New York City's median home price is $69,000 higher ($237,000 as opposed to Portland's $168,000). Yet, the NAHB considers New York City more affordable than Portland! [FN243]
Why does the NAHB claim that New York is more affordable than Portland? The NAHB's affordability index is the percentage of homes allegedly "affordable" to a hypothetical household earning the median regional income. [FN244] Thus, NAHB reasons, New York is more affordable than Portland because New *38 York households earning the median income can allegedly afford 29.3% of homes, while Portland households earning Portland's median income can only afford 27.6% of homes. [FN245] This means that the prices of homes above the NAHB-designated "affordability level" (as well as the price and desirability of homes below this "affordability level") are irrelevant to the NAHB index.
Portland's apparent unaffordability may be related to the fact that the gap between Portland's most expensive and least expensive housing is smaller than similar gaps in New York or other cities. Thus, a homeowner who cannot afford the average house also cannot afford many of the area's cheaper-than-average houses. [FN246] For example, only about one-third of Portland-area homeowners have unusually high (50% over the regional median) or unusually low (50% below the regional median) housing costs. [FN247] In contrast, a majority of Los Angeles-area homeowners [FN248] and over 40% of New York-area homeowners have unusual housing costs. [FN249]
It follows that under the NAHB's criteria, the metropolitan areas with the largest gap between the most expensive and least expensive homes may seem *39 quite affordable, because such areas will have a large number of low-cost homes affordable to median-income homeowners. It further follows that the most dangerous cities are by definition relatively affordable under the NAHB's methodology, because the very cheap houses in expensive cities may be located in run-down, dangerous areas. [FN250]
The following hypothetical illustrates how the NAHB test may lead to absurd results. Imagine two cities, City A and City B. In both, the median housing price is $150,000. A household earning the median income can afford a $50,000 to $100,000 house, and any house costing under $50,000 is likely to be in a crime-ridden neighborhood and thus undesirable to all but the most adventurous (or desperate) homebuyers. Suppose that City A is a socially homogeneous city with very low crime rates, and that as a result the price gap between the best and the worst neighborhood is lower than in most big cities (as appears to be the case in Portland). [FN251] City A's housing prices are thus distributed as follows:

Over $200,000: 5%
$150-200,000: 40%
$100-150,000: 25%
$50-100,000: 20%
Under $50,000: 5%

Although City A has very few "high-end" houses, the remaining houses are so clustered in the $100,000 to $200,000 range that a median income household can afford only 25% of them. Thus, City A has an affordability index of 25 under the NAHB methodology. However, most of the low-end houses are not in crime-infested neighborhoods, so 20% of houses are both affordable and relatively desirable (i.e., not in a dangerous neighborhood). Thus, the real affordability index--that is, the percent of houses that are both affordable to middle-class homebuyers and located in neighborhoods that middle-class homebuyers would actually be willing to consider--is 20, almost as high as the NAHB affordability rating.
*40 Portland closely resembles City A. Portland's murder rate (5.3 murders per 100,000 residents in 1998) is lower than that of most big cities. [FN252] The Portland metropolitan area is significantly safer than most cities. [FN253] Portland's urban poverty rate is lower than the national poverty rate [FN254] and (as in City A) the price gap between Portland's most and least expensive houses is lower than in other metropolitan areas. [FN255]
By comparison, City B is a two-class city. It has a number of relatively safe elite neighborhoods and/or suburbs, an equally large number of cheap, crime-infested slums, and a tiny middle class. As a result, its housing prices are distributed as follows:

Over $200,000: 40%
$150-200,000: 10%
$100-150,000: 5%
$50-100,000: 5%
Under $50,000: 40%

Because 45% of City B houses are theoretically affordable to a median-income household (i.e., one who can only afford a $100,000 house), the NAHB would give City B an affordability index of 45--nearly twice that of City A. But because of City B's crime problem, many of its housing units are simply unthinkable to the average homebuyer concerned about his or her safety. In fact, when the dangerous "under $50,000" neighborhoods are excluded, City B's affordability rating drops to 5, one-fourth that of City A.
Thus, the NAHB index yields absurd results because it systematically disfavors relatively safe, homogenous cities and metropolitan areas (like City A and Portland), and favors cities and metropolitan areas sharply divided into rich and poor, safe and unsafe (such as city B). The relative affordability of America's most dangerous regions supports this interpretation of NAHB's tabulations. The five metropolitan areas with the highest violent crime rates in 1998 all had higher *41 "affordability scores" than Portland. [FN256] Table 9 compares Portland with two of these "City B" -type areas.


TABLE 9: HOUSING COSTS IN NEW YORK, PORTLAND, AND LOS ANGELES (4th quarter
1998) [FN257]

Median income (in Median home price (in NAHB
thousands) thousands) score affordability
Portland 49.6 155 38.7
Los Angeles 49.8 179 50
New York 49.8 160 56

Los Angeles and New York had median incomes virtually identical to those of Portland, and higher median home prices. Yet according to the NAHB, Los Angeles and New York (whose violent crime rates were nearly double those of Portland) [FN258] are far more affordable, presumably because they have more extremely inexpensive neighborhoods. For example, New York and Los Angeles have higher median home prices than Portland, [FN259] but also have more homes that cost under $200 per month than Portland. [FN260] Thus, the NAHB index appears to *42 reward cities with a profusion of dangerous, low-cost slums. The NAHB index of affordability may be flawed in other respects. The index fails to consider Oregon's lack of a sales tax (thus underestimating buyers' income). It also fails to account for the fact that second- and third-time buyers benefit from the rising resale value of their first homes, because they can make larger down payments on later homes. [FN261]
Even though Portland's housing prices have exploded in recent years, its overall cost of living has not. Between 1995 and 1999, Portland's consumer price index for all items increased by 12.7%--no more than in Denver (12.7%), and less than in Seattle (13.5%). [FN262] Thus, there is no reason to believe that Portland consumers are being impoverished by high housing prices.
In sum, Portland's property values have indeed gone up over the past decade, but its price increases and home values are in line with those of comparable metropolitan areas. The UGB may have had a marginal effect on Portland's housing costs, but it has hardly been the disaster that some have claimed. [FN263]

B. Portland's So-Called Congestion Crisis
Environmentalists argue that suburban sprawl increases traffic congestion, by increasing the number of cars on the road and the distances that drivers travel. [FN264] UGB critics argue, on the other hand, that anti-sprawl policies such as UGBs actually increase congestion by forcing a constant or growing number of *43 cars onto the same amount of land. [FN265] It follows, according to UGB critics, that Portland's UGB, by increasing density, has increased traffic congestion. [FN266]
The Texas Transportation Institute (TTI), a state research agency affiliated with Texas A & M University, [FN267] regularly conducts "urban mobility studies" that evaluate the extent of congestion in America's largest metropolitan areas. Its 2001 study [FN268] contains numerous measures of congestion trends, including increases in annual delay per person. [FN269] TTI ranked Portland number eleven (out of sixty-eight metropolitan areas ranked) in the 1982-99 increase in delay caused by traffic congestion--that is, TTI found that congestion increased at a more rapid rate in Portland than in all but ten metropolitan areas. But two of those ten were comparable areas which lacked UGBs for some or all of the relevant period--Seattle (no. 5) and Denver (no. 8). [FN270] In other words, congestion increased dramatically in Portland, but no more dramatically than in other areas without UGBs.
Moreover, there is no reason to believe that Portland's congestion increase was the result of increased density. According to TTI, Portland's population density actually decreased slightly from 1982 to 1999, from 3230 people per square mile to 3040. [FN271]
*44 Seattle's brief experience with UGBs supports the view that UGBs do not cause congestion. Seattle instituted UGBs in 1994 [FN272]--so if UGBs cause congestion, congestion in Seattle should have risen more dramatically in recent years than in earlier years. Instead, Seattle's delay per person exploded from nineteen hours per driver in 1982, to fifty-five hours in 1992, and then decreased to fifty-three hours in 1999. [FN273] Thus, the Seattle UGB has not increased traffic congestion.
It could be argued that the UGB has failed to dramatically increase congestion only because Portland has not yet become particularly dense, and if Portland does not dilute or eliminate the UGB in the future, density may increase and thus cause congestion. [FN274] The link between density and congestion, however, is weak. Table 10 lists the urbanized areas with more congestion than Portland, and compares their density to Portland.


TABLE 10: DENSITY AND DELAY PER PERSON, 1999 [FN275]

Delay per person (hours) Population per square mile
Los Angeles 56 5575
Atlanta 53 1585
Seattle 53 2295
Houston 50 1830
Dallas 46 1455
Washington 46 3420
Austin 45 1585
Denver 45 2240
St. Louis 44 1775
Orlando 42 1780
Miami 42 3785
Boston 42 2605
San Jose 42 4340
Nashville 42 1085
San Francisco 42 3205
San Berardino 38 2600
Minneapolis 38 1900
San Diego 37 3575
Indianapolis 37 2050
Louisville 37 2060
Tampa 35 1530
Portland 34 3040

*45 Table 10 shows no link between density and congestion: of twenty-one areas with more congestion than Portland, fifteen (including Seattle and Denver) are less densely populated. Thus, density either (a) does not cause traffic congestion or (b) increases traffic congestion so minutely that the congestion-causing effect of density is overwhelmed by other relevant factors.
In sum, traffic congestion in metropolitan Portland has grown about as fast as in other western metropolitan areas without UGBs--a fact that suggests UGBs neither cause nor cure traffic congestion to a significant extent. And if the UGB increases regionwide density in the future, traffic congestion will not necessarily increase as a result, because there is no clear correlation between regionwide population density and regionwide traffic congestion.

C. Density, UGBs, and Air Quality
Air quality is widely acknowledged to be linked in some way to density, sprawl, and UGBs, but there is no consensus as to how these problems are linked to UGBS. Environmentalists assert that sprawl creates pollution by increasing automobile use, [FN276] and that Oregon's land use policies might therefore limit pollution by limiting sprawl. [FN277] UGB opponents argue, however, that UGB-induced increases in density will lead to increases in pollution. One commentator reasons that "[a]s density rises, so does congestion." [FN278] "[G]iven the fact that air pollution rises as urban automobile speeds decline and as 'stop and start' operation increases, the result is greater air pollution." [FN279]
As noted above, [FN280] Portland's traffic congestion is no worse than that of less densely populated metropolitan areas, including otherwise comparable regions such as Seattle and Denver. [FN281] If Portland's policies are not certain to *46 cause increased traffic congestion, those policies obviously will not cause congestion-related pollution.
Moreover, air pollution in Portland is comparable to that of nearby metropolitan areas. Table 11 lists trends in carbon monoxide emissions for Portland and comparable western metropolitan areas.


TABLE 11: CARBON MONOXIDE EMISSIONS IN PARTS PER MILLION, 1989-98 [FN282]

1989 1998 % REDUCTION
Denver 7.8 3.9 50.0
Portland 8.2 5.1 37.8
Salt Lake City 7.7 4.9 36.3
Seattle 8.5 4.5 47.0

Table 11 reveals that all four metropolitan areas reduced carbon monoxide pollution by roughly similar amounts, and that Portland was slightly less successful in reducing carbon monoxide than Seattle and Denver but slightly more successful than Salt Lake City. Thus, it appears that Oregon's land use and transportation policies, to the extent those policies differ from those of other western states, have not significantly affected air quality. Portland's rather ordinary air quality performance should not be surprising, in view of Portland's apparent failure to reduce automobile use during the 1990s. [FN283]
It could be argued that even if the UGB has not yet increased pollution, it will do so in the future by encouraging higher density (which will in turn allegedly increase pollution by increasing traffic congestion). [FN284] To be sure, a scintilla of evidence supports this theory: Los Angeles has a higher population density than any other urbanized area [FN285] and has more carbon monoxide pollution *47 than most other large urbanized areas. [FN286] But Los Angeles is unusual in that it combines high density with high automobile dependency, [FN287] perhaps because its central core is far less dense than that of less automobile-oriented cities: the central city of Los Angeles had only 7426 people per square mile in 1990. [FN288] By contrast, each of the eight large metropolitan areas included in the study where at least 10% of commuters used public transit in 1990 [FN289] included or was near a central city with 9500 persons or more per square mile. [FN290]
Metropolitan areas with high levels of public transit use tend to have relatively clean air. Table 12 lists the five metropolitan areas with the highest public transit ridership, and their pollutant levels, and compares them to Portland and other comparable metropolitan areas.


TABLE 12: PUBLIC TRANSIT RIDERSHIP AND CARBON MONOXIDE, 1998

% of commuters 1998 using Carbon monoxide emissions
public transit [FN291] (parts/million) [FN292]
New York City 47.3 3.7
San Francisco 19.5 3.5
Chicago 17.1 3.4
Boston 14.2 2.9
Washington 13.7 3.3
Denver 4.4 3.9
Portland 6.0 5.1
Salt Lake City 3.0 4.9
Seattle 7.4 4.5

*48 The most public transit-friendly metropolitan areas are all less polluted than Portland, Denver, Seattle, or Salt Lake City. Therefore, if Portland can ever densify its central core and reduce automobile dependency to the extent that those metropolitan areas have done, air pollution is unlikely to increase.

D. Do UGBs Reduce Housing Quality?
UGB opponents argue that even if the Portland UGB does not increase housing costs, traffic congestion, or air pollution, it has reduced the quality of the housing stock by reducing the amount of buildable land, thus reducing home and lot sizes. For example, one anti-UGB article is titled: Squeezed Out: No Swingset, No Sandbox, No Space Left for the American Dream. [FN293] The article asserts that because few new homes are built on half-acre lots, "[t]he American Dream is dead in Portland." [FN294] Similarly, one anti-UGB activist asserts that if the UGB is not expanded or eliminated, "[p]eople will be crowded together, living on small lots." [FN295]
But in fact, the specter of a hyper-dense Portland is imaginary; Portlanders' homes and lots are as large as ever. Between 1986 and 1995, the median-sized owner-occupied home in Portland grew from 1674 square feet [FN296] to 1764 square feet. [FN297] The median lot size grew slightly, from .22 acre [FN298] to .23 acre. [FN299] The number of houses sitting on over half an acre of land grew from 74,000 [FN300] to 98,700. [FN301] And during the 1990s, "nearly 800,000 of the 1.4 million people living in the Portland area . . . saw no change in the density of their neighborhoods." [FN302] As a result, "only 5% of the region's residents live in areas with population density greater than 10,000 people per square mile." [FN303] In *49 Portland, as in other areas, more people are building bigger houses on more land. [FN304]
Critics argue that even if Portland has no density crisis today, a refusal to expand the UGB could eventually force Portlanders to live in an overcrowded, congested environment. [FN305] But in fact, Portland has plenty of room to grow. The city of Portland has just over 529,000 people living within its 124.7 square miles. [FN306] If the city's population tripled, it would have about 1.587 million people living within those 124.7 square miles, thus creating a density of 12,726 people per square mile, which is still a lower density than that of San Francisco. [FN307] In other words, if a million people moved to Portland in the next few decades, every single one of them could, in theory, be placed in the city of Portland without either making Portland inordinately dense or increasing suburban densities by one iota.

E. The Libertarian Argument Against UGBs
Libertarians argue that regardless of its utilitarian benefits, Portland's UGB should not be imitated because restricting landowners' use of their land violates their property rights. [FN308] This argument makes sense in principle: in a society that truly valued minimal government, any form of land use regulation would obviously be inappropriate. [FN309]
However, the United States is not such a society: even in colonial times, states and cities enacted planning statutes similar to UGBs. For example, the *50 Massachusetts Bay Colony "prohibited dwellings more than one-half mile from town meeting houses without court permission." [FN310] Today, as UGB critic Clint Bolick admits, "minimum lot sizes and restrictions on multiple uses, often popular tactics among suburban governments to keep their communities pristine and exclusive, definitely contribute to 'sprawling' suburbs." [FN311] A typical zoning ordinance has separate zones for: single-family large lot, single-family medium, single-family standard, multi-family low density, multi-family medium density, multi-family high density, general office, neighborhood commercial, community commercial, service commercial, central business district, limited industrial, and heavy industrial. [FN312] These regulations contribute to sprawl by separating residential and commercial uses, thereby making it difficult for people to go from their residences to shops and workplaces without driving. [FN313] Municipalities also reduce housing supplies and force Americans to drive by mandating minimum lot sizes and house sizes within zones. [FN314] These regulations were frequently enacted for the purpose of increasing housing prices. [FN315] They also inadvertently reduce transit use, because as residences are spread farther apart, fewer people can conveniently walk to bus and train stops. [FN316] If pro-sprawl land use restrictions such as separation of land uses, minimum house sizes, and minimum lot sizes do not unduly infringe landowners' rights, neither do UGBs.
Similarly, UGB critics often support pro-sprawl government transportation policies. For decades, government has accelerated sprawl by building new roads into suburbia, thus encouraging development to shift from cities to suburbs. [FN317] But many critics of UGBs and other anti-sprawl measures are less than *51 critical of road spending. For example: (1) The Independence Institute, which purports to address "public policy issues from a free-market, pro-freedom perspective" [FN318] published an anti-UGB paper asserting that "[f]or traffic congestion to be mitigated . . . [r]oadway expansions will be necessary." [FN319] (2) Steven Hayward of the Heritage Foundation complained in a 1998 article that "Portland's planners . . . are substituting political decisions for marketplace decisions," [FN320] yet claimed in the same article that Portland will suffer increased traffic congestion because "the region deliberately avoids road-building." [FN321] (3) Grant Gulibon, a policy analyst for Pennsylvania's conservative Commonwealth Foundation, complains that the UGB "created an artificial scarcity of land . . . . Whenever a commodity becomes scarce the price goes up." [FN322] Yet Gulibon asserts that "[t]he reason [new roads] fill up right away is because you didn't build enough in the first place." [FN323]
UGBs undeniably increase government's voice in land use decisions--but so do a variety of well-established government policies, some of which are supported even by prominent UGB critics. Thus, UGBs are not uniquely intrusive.


VI. Conclusion
As explained above, UGBs are probably constitutional under Supreme Court Takings Clause precedent for two reasons. First, a UGB will rarely, if ever, cause a complete deprivation of economically beneficial use, and is thus unlikely to be a compensable "total taking" under Lucas and Palazzolo. Second, UGBs *52 will generally not be compensable "partial takings" under the Penn Central balancing test, because they are typically justified by a legitimate state purpose (that of preventing the urbanization of rural areas) and will, if prudently drafted, rarely interfere with landowners' investment-backed expectations.
The question of whether UGBs are wise public policy is a more difficult one. The Oregon UGB has apparently had one major benefit: enhancing consumer choice, by making the city of Portland a viable lifestyle choice for middle-class Portlanders, instead of merely a holding pen for people too poor to move to suburbia. And by making it easier for Portlanders to live in the city, the UGB has arguably made it somewhat easier for them to use public transit instead of being enslaved by their cars.
In other ways, Portland has continued to evolve in the same directions as nearby metropolitan areas without UGBs. On the negative side, this means that the UGB has not had an enormous effect upon automobile use, traffic congestion, or urban consumption of farmland. Although Portland's air is cleaner than it was a decade ago, the same is true for other western cities without UGBs. On the positive side, the UGB has not led to the horrors imagined by UGB critics. Portland's real estate is not significantly more expensive than that of comparable western cities, its traffic congestion is no more annoying, and its air is no more polluted. In sum, UGB supporters and opponents alike may have overestimated both the positive and negative effects of UGBs.

(footnotes deleted due to length of article)

Posted by lewyn at 3:05 PM EST
Updated: Monday, 17 January 2005 5:19 PM EST
note on copryight
Law journal articles posted on this blog are with the permission of the relevant journals.

Posted by lewyn at 3:03 PM EST
my Ecology L.Q. article
30 Ecology L.Q. 189


Ecology Law Quarterly
2003


Books Reviewed


*189 HOW CITY HALL CAUSES SPRAWL: A CASE STUDY --A REVIEW ESSAY BY MICHAEL
LEWYN OF ATLANTA: RACE, CLASS AND URBAN EXPANSION BY LARRY KEATING: TEMPLE
UNIVERSITY PRESS, 2001, PP. 248. $69.50 (CLOTH), $22.95 (PAPER)


Michael Lewyn [FNa1]


Copyright ? 2003 The Regents of the University of California; Michael Lewyn


INTRODUCTION: SEGREGATION AND POLLUTION IN SPRAWL CITY
Journalists and scholars have repeatedly termed Atlanta "sprawl's poster child," [FN1] because the inequality, [FN2] urban decay, [FN3] and air pollution [FN4] commonly associated with suburban sprawl [FN5] have reached extreme forms in Atlanta. For example:
* While Atlanta's suburbs have grown explosively, the city of Atlanta has actually lost population in recent decades. *190 Metropolitan Atlanta's population grew by over 80% between 1980 and 2000, [FN6] but the city of Atlanta is actually less populated than it was in 1980, [FN7] and it has lost over half its 1960 white population. [FN8] The city's depopulation has been accompanied by poverty: while only 6.7% of the region's households earn less than $10,000 per year, [FN9] 17% of city households do so. [FN10]
* As jobs have followed people to suburbia, Atlanta's central business district has stagnated while its suburban employment centers have grown. In 1966, downtown Atlanta contained more than two-thirds of public, corporate and private office space in the Atlanta region. [FN11] By 1997, just 13.3% of regional private office space was located in downtown Atlanta. [FN12] The predominantly white [FN13] northern suburbs contain all but one of the region's suburban office submarkets, 65.9% of regional research-and-development office space, and 52% of regional employment. [FN14] In recent decades, much of downtown Atlanta has been virtually empty at night: [FN15] in the words of travel *191 writer Arthur Frommer, "a graveyard, a scene of death and desolation, a nullity." [FN16]
* The dominance of suburbia has, in turn, increased automobile dependency, because suburban office buildings are often spaced so far apart that walking between them (or between the office buildings and any other form of land use) is extremely difficult. [FN17] For example, one suburban commercial district, the Roswell/Alpharetta submarket, spreads less than a fifth as much office space as is contained in Atlanta's central business district over a linear distance seven times as great. [FN18]
* The suburban job market is inaccessible to the predominantly African-American, non-driving poor of the inner city. Because Atlanta-area jobs have moved to suburbs, [FN19]where public transit is minimal, [FN20] they are virtually inaccessible to non-drivers. Thirty-nine percent of all black households in Atlanta do not have access to cars, [FN21] and in 2000, only 34% of the region's jobs were within a one-hour public transit ride of low-income urban neighborhoods. [FN22] Income inequality between white and black neighborhoods has exploded: in 1950, the median family income for predominantly white census tracts was just over twice the figure for black census tracts, while the white census tract/black census tract income ratio had increased to 5.28 in 1990. [FN23]
* Atlantans drive further distances than most other Americans, causing pollution that substantially endangers public health. In *192 2000, the average Atlantan drove 33.8 miles per day, about 50% more than the national average for residents of large metropolitan areas. [FN24] Atlanta's auto dependency has contributed to the region's air pollution. In both 2000 and 2001, Greater Atlanta had higher levels of ozone (a pollutant partially caused by automobile fumes) [FN25] than all but five other American metropolitan areas. [FN26] Between 1998 and 2000, metropolitan Atlanta's most polluted county experienced 86 days on which ozone levels were at levels unhealthy for groups especially sensitive to pollution [FN27] (such as "children, the elderly, and those with chronic lung disease" [FN28]), and 31 days on which the air was unhealthy for the community as a whole. [FN29]
Some commentators have blamed suburban sprawl on decisions made by federal and state governments, [FN30] while others assert that sprawl merely expresses consumer preferences. [FN31] But in Atlanta: Race, Class and *193 Urban Expansion, Larry Keating, a professor of city planning at the Georgia Institute of Technology, [FN32] focuses on a third factor: municipal incompetence. This essay generally endorses Keating's view that local governments have contributed to Atlanta's problems, [FN33] but suggests that Keating has insufficiently described the relationship between zoning laws and Atlanta's sprawl, and has failed to fully discuss some effects of this sprawl, such as crime and inferior public education.


I. ATLANTA'S REIGN OF ERROR
Keating focuses his analysis on the city of Atlanta's highway policies, on ill-conceived mass transit and zoning policies, and on the city's imprudent urban renewal policies.

A. The Highway Fiasco
Throughout America, state and federal governments have accelerated suburban sprawl by building highways in rural areas and suburbs. [FN34] Highways facilitate access to suburban and rural land, thus making such land more appealing to developers and prospective residents. [FN35] As Keating points out, Atlanta politicians have been just as enthusiastic about sprawl-creating highways as their state and federal counterparts. As early as 1946, consultants hired by Atlanta's business leaders issued a report that urged the area's local governments to finance *194 a network of expressways radiating outward from downtown Atlanta to its suburbs. [FN36] Business leaders believed that the highways would make downtown Atlanta more prosperous by facilitating access to downtown from the suburbs and from the city's outskirts. [FN37] With the support of Atlanta politicians including Mayor William Hartsfield, the highways opened in the late 1950s. [FN38]
As early as the 1960s, this first generation of expressways facilitated massive "white flight" [FN39] to suburbia: the city lost over 60,000 whites between 1960 and 1970. [FN40] Emigrants to suburbia also followed the expressways, moving up I-75 (one of the city's north-south expressways) and I-85 (the other north-south expressway) [FN41] to Cobb, DeKalb and Gwinnett Counties. [FN42] Keating points out that, additionally, at this time the city lost industrial jobs to suburban areas along the expressways. [FN43]
In 1961 Hartsfield retired [FN44] and was replaced by Ivan Allen Jr., a prominent member of Atlanta's downtown business elite. [FN45] Before starting his campaign for mayor, Allen pledged that continued highway construction would be one of the city's major redevelopment objectives. [FN46] As promised, I-285 (known to most Atlantans as "the Perimeter"), a *195 highway encircling the city, opened in 1969. [FN47] Like Atlanta's first generation of expressways, I-285 dispersed Atlantans to suburbia. [FN48] By 1995, almost 38 million square feet of office space had sprung up on and beyond the Perimeter, more than twice the amount remaining in downtown Atlanta. [FN49] Three of metropolitan Atlanta's major commercial districts are along the Perimeter. [FN50]
By the 1980s, expressway-generated sprawl had eviscerated Atlanta's core. Between 1970 and 1980, the city of Atlanta lost 70,000 people, [FN51] as both people and jobs moved to the suburbs along I-75, I-85 and I-285. [FN52] In addition to luring the middle class to suburbia, the expressways had turned downtown Atlanta into a wasteland of parking lots and off-ramps. According to one estimate, 50% of downtown land was engulfed by a tidal wave of expressways, streets and parking, and "hundreds of acres were consumed by interchanges" on the fringes of downtown. [FN53]
Despite these emerging problems, city politicians refused to change course. Keating describes how, in the 1980s, business interests in Buckhead (a commercial district six miles north of downtown and within the city limits) [FN54] lobbied for Georgia 400, [FN55] an expressway that would link Buckhead with a suburban highway of the same name [FN56] and with I-285. [FN57] Just as Atlanta's downtown elite had once believed that highways would facilitate downtown commerce by making downtown more accessible *196 from Atlanta's suburbs, [FN58] Buckhead businesspeople believed that highways would aid Buckhead's commerce by making Buckhead more accessible to suburbanites. [FN59] Some business leaders also admitted that such "highways to the suburbs made them less dependent on an increasingly black city-workforce." [FN60] Nevertheless, the Atlanta City Council approved the highway in 1989, [FN61] and the Georgia 400 extension opened in 1993. [FN62]
Keating asserts that, like earlier highways, the Georgia 400 extension appears to have created a new generation of sprawl: the Roswell/Alpharetta suburban office submarket, built entirely during the 1990s, now encompasses more than 9 million square feet of office space along 10 miles of Georgia 400. [FN63] Suburbs served by Georgia 400 experienced enormous residential growth as well: between 1990 and 2000, Roswell's population increased by nearly 60%, and Alpharetta's population nearly tripled, [FN64] while the city of Atlanta's population increased by just 5%, [FN65] only partially reversing the city's losses in the 1970s and 1980s. [FN66]
For over 50 years, Atlanta's politicians, with business support, followed the same strategy: build road after road after road to link city and suburb. [FN67] Keating points out that instead of encouraging suburbanites to work in the city, these roads encouraged urbanites to move their businesses and families to the suburbs, turning Atlanta into (in the words *197 of one local newspaper columnist) "the incredible shrinking city" [FN68] with a "largely vacant" [FN69] downtown. The highways also reduced transit ridership and increased Atlantans' dependence on automobiles, by encouraging Atlantans to move to suburbs with minimal or nonexistent public transit. [FN70]

B. The Transit and Zoning Debacles
Keating next discusses the ways in which Atlanta's local government leaders' development of a mass transit system and related zoning regulations further contributed to sprawl. Although Atlanta's business and political leaders favored highways, they also sought to expand public transit. As early as 1954, a regional planning commission suggested that the city would need an expanded public transit system "within a few years." [FN71] In 1960, Ivan Allen, who was president of the Atlanta Chamber of Commerce at that time, announced that a rapid transit system would be part of his redevelopment program. [FN72] In 1961, a regional planning commission recommended a fixed-rail system that would connect the city with five suburban counties (Fulton, [FN73] DeKalb, [FN74] Cobb, Gwinnett, and Clayton). [FN75] Two counties (Fulton and DeKalb Counties) approved construction in a 1971 referendum, [FN76] and construction of the rail system began shortly thereafter. [FN77]
The Metropolitan Atlanta Rapid Transit Authority ("MARTA") has been only a qualified success. On the positive side, transit plays a significant role in downtown commuting: 28.6% of downtown work trips involve public transit. [FN78] But service to Atlanta's suburbs has been a *198 tougher nut to crack. Of the five suburban counties that were originally slated for MARTA service (Fulton, DeKalb, Cobb, Gwinnett and Clayton), three (Cobb, Gwinnett, and Clayton) refused MARTA service, [FN79] and until 2001 two of the five (Clayton and Gwinnett) still had no public transit whatsoever. [FN80] Not surprisingly, only 4% of commuters in the Atlanta region use public transit to get to work. [FN81] In other words, MARTA adequately serves downtown Atlanta but is of little value in most of Atlanta's suburbs.
Keating suggests that rapid rail was doomed to fail because of Atlanta's low population density. [FN82] He reasons: "only where there are significant concentrations of both residences and jobs does a rail system attract enough riders to justify the initial investment . . . . Atlanta, having experienced most of its growth during the automobile era, is a low-density city with widely dispersed residences and jobs." [FN83] Although MARTA planners were aware of this problem, they argued that Atlanta and its suburbs could create density (and thus increase rail ridership) by using zoning regulations to encourage development within walking distance of its stations and rail lines. [FN84] Shortly after the passage of the *199 1971 referendum authorizing rail service, the city hired consultants to rewrite the city's zoning ordinance to shift high-density development to areas immediately surrounding rail stations. [FN85] But Atlanta's business community (which, ironically, had supported creation of the rail system), [FN86] sabotaged that system by mounting an intensive campaign to defeat the proposed zoning changes, eventually persuading the City Council to pass a watered-down ordinance which permitted high-density development in areas far from rail stations. [FN87] As a result of these anti-transit zoning policies, the rail system has not attracted as much compact development around stations as it could have. Because fewer people live or work within walking distance of MARTA stations than would have been the case had zoning codes been more favorable, ridership is lower than it could have been, which, in turn, means that Atlanta continues to be an automobile-oriented city. [FN88]
Keating describes the way in which this pattern was repeated in Atlanta's northern suburbs. In the late 1980s, MARTA directors decided to extend its rail service into the northern suburbs, especially the commercial district in the north-central section of I-285. [FN89] Charles Loudermilk, chairman of the MARTA Board of Directors, endorsed the new rail line on the ground that "we need to get the unemployed people in the city's core out to where the jobs are" [FN90]-an argument that would have made sense had suburban jobs been concentrated near rail stations. However, suburban municipalities made the same mistake that the city of Atlanta made a few years earlier: they were willing to throw taxpayers' money at a rail line, but were unwilling to concentrate commerce or housing along the rail corridors. [FN91] As a result, suburban MARTA stations are miles away from most office buildings. [FN92] Thus, MARTA's ability to bring city residents to suburban jobs is quite limited. [FN93]

*200 C. The Redevelopment Fiasco(s)
The Atlanta city government has repeatedly sought to revitalize the city through a variety of "redevelopment" schemes, including expressways, a civic center, and a convention center. These projects have failed to stem downtown's long-term decline, [FN94] and, as Keating points out, have in fact been counterproductive, spurring white flight from the city of Atlanta while failing to revitalize the city's central business district.


1. Destruction of Urban Neighborhoods
Some of Atlanta's redevelopment projects have been highly disruptive to neighborhoods surrounding downtown Atlanta, particularly impacting low-income, minority communities. For example, when consultants hired at the behest of Atlanta business leaders planned the first Atlanta-area expressways in the 1940s, they could have minimized highway-related neighborhood destruction by routing the highways through industrial districts. [FN95] Instead, they proposed that the city raze portions of several low-income, mostly African-American, neighborhoods. [FN96] For example, the city's north-south expressway cut through the middle of Auburn Avenue, historically the city's major black commercial district. [FN97] According to Keating, business leaders wished to "remove as many poor blacks from the downtown area as possible . . . [and] create a buffer between the [central business district] and the remaining portions of those neighborhoods." [FN98] After the first expressways were built, the city used federal "urban renewal" [FN99] funds to clear land for redevelopment on both sides of the city's north-south expressway. [FN100] The combination of highway construction and urban *201 renewal eliminated half of one low-income white neighborhood and portions of several poor black neighborhoods. [FN101]
Similarly, in the early 1960s, the city spent $9 million [FN102] to raze Buttermilk Bottoms (a low-income neighborhood northeast of downtown) [FN103] in order to build a civic center. [FN104]
A further example of this racially-motivated destruction of neighborhoods was a late 1960's initiative to make Atlanta a major destination for conventions. Downtown business leaders persuaded the state government to subsidize a convention center [FN105] on the western edge of downtown. [FN106] In order to isolate conventioneers from low-income blacks, the city destroyed low-income neighborhoods surrounding the site of the convention center. [FN107] Indeed, Atlanta politicians may have been too successful at isolating conventioneers: Keating points out that because the convention center is at the western edge of downtown Atlanta, conventioneers do not find it tremendously convenient to walk from the center to the heart of the central business district, thus making downtown Atlanta even more vacant than it would otherwise be. [FN108]


2. How Urban Renewal Caused "White Flight"
Atlanta's urban renewal and expressway programs displaced about 67,000- 75,000 people [FN109] in about 20,000 households, [FN110] which is over 20% of the city's 1950 population [FN111] and includes more than half the city's black population. [FN112] Yet the city's housing authority only built 4,762 *202 potential replacement housing units. Thus, between 14,000 and 17,000 households were forced to move but did not receive replacement housing. [FN113] Instead of moving to housing projects on the city's fringes, Keating observes, displaced low-income blacks quickly moved into other areas near downtown, [FN114] spurring "white flight" from those neighborhoods. [FN115] In the words of former city planning director Leon Eplan: "A neighborhood was redeveloped and its residents moved to an adjoining neighborhood and then those people moved to the next . . . . All social organization was destroyed." [FN116]
By the 1970s, after decades of "redevelopment" designed to displace blacks from downtown Atlanta and nearby neighborhoods, downtown Atlanta was nevertheless ringed by black neighborhoods. [FN117] The same pattern exists today: according to the 2000 Census, the neighborhoods closest to Atlanta's central business district are three-quarters black [FN118] and are generally low-income. [FN119] The city's program of ethnic cleansing was thus as fruitless as it was racist. Indeed, the city's policies appear to have spurred white flight to suburbia by displacing low-income blacks, and thus encouraging them to move into then-white neighborhoods.


II. UNADDRESSED ISSUES
Although Keating has correctly identified some of the major causes of Atlanta's sprawl-induced decline, he neglected to discuss other important factors. Most importantly, although Keating emphasizes that Atlanta and its suburbs did not effectively use their zoning codes to increase transit ridership, he could have devoted more attention to the municipal zoning codes that actually reduced transit ridership by lowering *203 population densities. Keating does mention that rather than trusting the free market, some Atlanta suburbs have used their zoning codes to dictate low density. For example, Cobb County prohibits apartments with over 12 units per acre, even though garden apartments in other areas typically have densities as high as 20 units per acre. [FN120] Similar zoning restrictions increase the size of single-family homes. Even within the city of Atlanta, zoning laws require homes in some areas to be on two acres of land. [FN121] Fulton County has established a minimum lot size of two acres for portions of the county, and Cobb County has followed suit. [FN122] Such restrictions appear to have limited the supply of small-lot housing: the average lot size of a single family home in metro Atlanta is 0.78 acres, more than three times that of Dallas, Houston, Phoenix or Tampa. [FN123]
Keating points out that such zoning restrictions raise the cost of housing and thus enforce racial and class segregation by keeping inexpensive housing out of affluent neighborhoods, [FN124] but he fails to point out that Atlanta-area zoning laws, by reducing density, also reduce the number of people who live near streets served by bus and rail stops, which in turn reduces transit ridership. [FN125] Such restrictions are not limited to neighborhoods with minimal transit service. For example, the area near MARTA's Indian Creek rail station in DeKalb County is zoned solely for single-family homes. [FN126] Similarly, Sandy Springs, an unincorporated area bordering Atlanta, [FN127] has three MARTA rail *204 stations [FN128] - yet Fulton County policy generally bans new apartments in Sandy Springs. [FN129] Even office space near MARTA stations can be controversial. For example, in 2001 a developer asked Fulton County to rezone land across the street from a Sandy Springs MARTA station for offices and retail space. In response to anti-density complaints from nearby homeowners, the county ordered the developer to reduce the amount of office space involved by two-thirds. [FN130] Keating's analysis of Atlanta local government's failed policies would have been strengthened by a discussion of how these anti-density policies further exacerbated the effects of sprawl.
Furthermore, because Keating focuses on a few key issues, he gives relatively short shrift to urban problems that are less obviously related to redevelopment policy, such as Atlanta's "disturbingly high crime rate" [FN131] and its "inferior public school system." [FN132] These problems, however, have been at least partially caused by the blunders discussed above. By encouraging middle-class flight to suburbia, the city's highway and urban renewal policies caused the city of Atlanta to become poorer than its suburban neighbors. [FN133] Low-income cities and neighborhoods tend to have more street crime. [FN134] Such areas also have less prestigious schools, because children from low-income households tend to be less prepared for school and thus less likely to achieve academically. [FN135] Moreover, low-income cities also have smaller tax bases, which may affect their *205 educational systems. [FN136] So by encouraging middle-class migration to suburbia, Atlanta's mistakes also led to high crime and inferior schools.


CONCLUSION
All too often, cities have been viewed as helpless victims of sprawl or as obsolete institutions unable to withstand market forces. Keating shows that in metropolitan Atlanta, local governments' own decisions contributed to auto-dependent suburban sprawl, through municipal support for sprawl-creating highways, ineffective public transit and zoning policies, and redevelopment policies that destabilized urban neighborhoods and spurred migration to suburbia. It has been argued that "[g]overnment had tried to control the pattern of development in metropolitan Atlanta, and for the most part, it had failed." [FN137] In fact, Atlanta-area governments have tried to control the pattern of development, by mandating anti-density, anti-transit land use rules--and have in fact succeeded in dictating that pattern of development.
Although Keating does not set out a comprehensive reform agenda, his book nevertheless gives guidance to the next generation of municipal leaders, both in Atlanta and in other cities wishing to avoid Atlanta's problems. If Atlantans dislike the status quo, they must reverse course: they must fight sprawl-producing highways, allow (or even encourage) developers to concentrate residences and jobs in areas served by public transit, and avoid civic projects that disrupt and displace urban communities.

[FNa1]. Associate Professor, John Marshall Law School. B.A., Wesleyan University; J.D., University of Pennsylvania Law School. I would like to thank Sally Flocks, Demetra Pappas, and Susan Rutherford for their helpful comments. Any errors of fact or logic are, of course, mine alone.

[FN1]. Robert D. Bullard et al. The Costs and Consequences of Suburban Sprawl: The Case of Metro Atlanta, 17 Ga. St. U. L. Rev. 935, 942 (2001) (terming metropolitan Atlanta "The Sprawl Poster Child"); Arthur C. Nelson, New Kid in Town: the Georgia Regional Transportation Authority and its Role in Managing Growth in Metropolitan Georgia, 35 Wake Forest L. Rev. 625, 626 (2000) ("Metropolitan Atlanta has become the 'poster child' for urban sprawl"); Brad Smith, Housing Study Criticizes Movement to Limit Sprawl, Tampa Trib., July 8, 2001, at 1; cf. George Galster et al., Wrestling Sprawl To The Ground: Defining and Measuring an Elusive Concept, 12 Housing Pol'y Debate 681, 706 (2001) (using numerous quantitative measurements to show that Atlanta is in fact more "sprawling" than other metropolitan areas).

[FN2]. Larry Keating, Atlanta: Race, Class and Urban Expansion 34 (2001) (asserting that the "suburbanization of jobs aggravated black unemployment"); Michael Lewyn, Suburban Sprawl: Not Just An Environmental Issue, 84 Marq. L. Rev. 301, 364-65 (2000) (asserting that growth of auto-dominant suburbs increases welfare dependency among carless poor).

[FN3]. Lewyn, supra note 2, at 301 (noting that "[s]ome central cities have been devastated by sprawl").

[FN4]. Roberta F. Mann, The (Not So) Little House on the Prairie: The Hidden Costs of the Home Mortgage Interest Deduction, 32 Ariz. St. L.J. 1347, 1373-74 (2000) (sprawl causes air pollution and congestion by increasing car use and thus emissions of pollutants from cars).

[FN5]. See William W. Buzbee, Sprawl's Dynamics: A Comparative Institutional Analysis Critique, 35 Wake Forest L. Rev. 509, 510 (2000) (defining sprawl as a "dispersed, low-density, metropolitan area form, where the metropolitan area's growth occurs principally on the urban periphery...Sprawling urban forms typically are car dependent and include dispersed single family homes and substantial distances between residential, business and retail areas").

[FN6]. U.S. Census Bureau, U.S. Commerce Dep't., Statistical Abstract of the United States 31 (121st ed. 2001.),
http://www.census.gov/prod/www/statistical-abstract-01.html [hereinafter 2001 Abstract] (area had just over 2.2 million residents in 1980 approximately over 4.1 million in 2000).

[FN7]. Id. at 35 (city had 495,000 residents in 1970, 425,000 in 1980, and 416,000 in 2000). However, the latter figure is an improvement over the city's 1990 nadir of 394,000 residents. Id.

[FN8]. The city of Atlanta had just over 300,000 white residents in 1960, and only 138,400 whites in 2000. See Bureau of the Census, U.S. Census of Population and Housing: 1960 at 14 (1962) (city of Atlanta included 266,186 whites in Fulton County and 34,449 in DeKalb County, for total of 300,635); 2001 Abstract, supra note 7, at 38 (2000 statistics). Since 1970, blacks have begun to move to Atlanta's suburbs as well. See Sheryll D. Cashin, Middle-Class Black Suburbs and the State of Integration: A Post-Integrationist Vision for Metropolitan America, 860 Cornell L. Rev. 729, 741-42 (2001) (in 1990, 64% of Atlanta-area blacks lived in suburbs, as opposed to 25% in 1970).

[FN9]. U.S. Census Bureau, U.S. Commerce Dep't., Census 2000 Demographic Profiles, Atlanta, GA MSA, 3, at http:// censtats.census.gov/data/GA/390130520.pdf [hereinafter Metro Profile].

[FN10]. U.S. Census Bureau, U.S. Commerce Dep't., Census 2000 Demographic Profiles, Atlanta, GA, 3, at http://censtats.census.gov/data/GA/1601304000.pdf [hereinafter City Profile].

[FN11]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 15.

[FN12]. Id. The rest of the city suffered from sprawl too: in 1980, 40% of the region's jobs were within the city of Atlanta-but in 1997, less than 20% of the region's jobs were located within the city limits. See Bullard et al. supra note 1, at 945.

[FN13]. See Perspective, The Dynamics of Change, Atlanta J. Const., Sept. 19, 1993, at G3 (northern suburbs contain 18% of region's black population and 70% of whites, while southern suburbs contain only 28% of whites and 43% of blacks).

[FN14]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 24.

[FN15]. Id. at 89, 109. Downtown Atlanta rebounded to some extent in the 1990s. For example, downtown's residential population increased by over 20% during the 1990s, to a still-anemic 0.6% of regional population. See Rebecca R. Sohmer & Robert E. Lang, Downtown Rebound, Fannie Mae Foundation Census Note, 5-6 (2001), http:// www.brookings.edu/dybdocroot/es/urban/census/downtownrebound.pdf.

[FN16]. Frederick Allen, Atlanta Rising 231 (1996).

[FN17]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 21.

[FN18]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 22. Residential densities are also extremely low in suburban Atlanta. See Wendell Cox, Demographia: U.S. Urbanized Areas, at http://www.demographia.com/dm-uas.htm (last visited Dec. 20, 2002) (suburban Atlanta has only 1754 people per square mile, 36.2% below U.S. metropolitan area average). Atlanta's low density makes jobs less accessible to nondrivers because as residences and businesses "are spread farther apart, fewer people can walk short distances to bus and train stops." Michael Lewyn, Campaign of Sabotage: Big Government's War Against Public Transportation, 26 Colum. J. Envtl. L. 259, 285 (2001).

[FN19]. See Bullard et al., supra note 1 at 945 (less than 20% of region's jobs in city of Atlanta).

[FN20]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 8 ("Adequate public transportation does not extend to the northern suburbs, so many poor blacks who do not own cars find it difficult to reach jobs in these outlying districts"); Lewyn, supra note 2, at 348 (noting that as of 2000, Gwinnett County, an Atlanta suburb with over half a million residents, had no public transit whatsoever).

[FN21]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 8.

[FN22]. Wendell Cox, A Common-Sense Approach to Transportation in the Atlanta Region Ch. 2, at http:// www.gppf.org/pubs/projects/transportation/transportation.htm (last updated April 11, 2002).

[FN23]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 39.

[FN24]. Fed. Highway Admin., U.S. Dep't. of Transp. Highway Statistics Table HM-72 (2000), at http://www.fhwa.dot.gov/ohim/hs00/hm72r2.htm (last visited Dec. 20, 2002) (national average for metro areas over 500,000 persons was 22.8 miles per day). Only three large metropolitan areas (Houston, Nashville, and Birmingham) had more vehicle miles traveled per person than Atlanta. Id.

[FN25]. See Bullard et al. supra note 1, at 971 n.192 (ozone caused by volatile organic compounds and nitrogen oxide, common components of car exhaust).

[FN26]. See American Lung Association, State of the Air 2002 Report 7 (2002), http://www.lungusa.org/air2001 [hereinafter State of the Air] (metropolitan Atlanta had the sixth worst ozone air pollution in America in both 2002 and 2001).

[FN27]. Id. Tables 4, 5 (labeling such days "Orange" days).

[FN28]. Id. at 1. Ozone causes asthma attacks and other respiratory illnesses in children, id. at 19, and increases the susceptibility of the elderly to influenza, pneumonia, and other infections. Id. at 20. Atlanta's air quality improvements during the 1996 Olympics suggest that Atlanta's high ozone levels are closely related to auto use: during the 1996 Summer Olympics, motor vehicle use declined, transit use increased, and emergency room visits by children for asthma dropped by more than forty percent. See Oliver A. Pollard, Smart Growth & Sustainable Transportation: Can We Get There From Here?, 29 Fordham Urb. L.J. 1529, 1556 (2002).

[FN29]. State of the Air, supra note 26, Tables 4, 5 (labeling such days "Red" and "Purple" days). "Red" days are "unhealthy" for the general public, and "Purple" days are "very unhealthy." Id. at 20. In 1998-2000, Fulton County had 22 "Red" days and 9 "Purple" days. Id. at 8-9.

[FN30]. See, e.g., Kevin J. Klesh, Urban Sprawl: Can The "Transportation Equity" Movement And Federal Transportation Policy Break Down Barriers To Regional Solutions?, 7 Envtl. Law. 649, 656 (2001) (federal General Accounting Office has "highlighted" federal policies causing sprawl, including highway-oriented transportation policies); Lewyn, supra note 2, at 305-29 (discussing pro-sprawl federal policies, but also emphasizing state pro-sprawl policies; for example, state education laws encouraged middle-class families to move to suburbs by requiring children to attend school in locality of residence).

[FN31]. See, e.g., Mark S. Davies, Understanding Sprawl: Lessons from Architecture for Legal Scholars, 99 Mich. L. Rev. 1520, 1525-26 (2001) (reviewing Andres Duany et al., Suburban Nation, the Rise of Sprawl and the Decline of the American Dream (2000)) ("the desire to live in a [suburban] home has overcome the well-known disadvantages caused by sprawl's reliance on the car"); Michael J. Stewart, Growth and Its Implications: An Evaluation of Tennessee's Growth Management Plan, 67 Tenn. L. Rev. 983, 994 (2000) ( "defenders of sprawl assert that sprawl is a result of people's preferences: Suburban sprawl exists because Americans want to live in these types of developments.").

[FN32]. Walter F. Roche, Jr., Federal Program Has Caused Angst Amid Hope, Balt. Sun, Sept. 24, 2001, at 4A (describing Keating's credentials, and quoting his views on public housing); David Goldberg, Boom & Doom, Atlanta J. Const., Jan. 20, 2002 at F1 (describing Keating's credentials, and quoting his views on The City In Mind, by James Howard Kunstler).

[FN33]. This is not to deny, however, that state and federal government policies have also contributed to suburban sprawl and urban decline. See Lewyn, supra note 2, at 305-29 (focusing on state and federal pro-sprawl policies, including massive highway spending, educational policies that contributed to urban schools' unpopularity with middle-class families, and housing policies that encouraged sprawl); Allen, supra note 16, at 143-44 (suggesting that city's compliance with federal desegregation requirements spurred white flight from city of Atlanta); Keating, supra note 2, at 195-96 (describing Georgia Department of Transportation as "the single entity with the most far-reaching power and influence" over Georgia development, because "its constant expansions of the region's highway system disperse new development and...largely determine where that development will occur.")

[FN34]. See supra note 33, infra note 35.

[FN35]. See Mann, supra note 4, at 1378 n.185 (federal General Accounting Office admits that "interstate highways improved access to developable land on the edge of metropolitan areas, supporting [suburban] sprawl development"); Klesh, supra note 30, at 656 (quoting General Accounting Office, Rep. No. GAO/RCED -99-87, Community Development: Extent of Federal Influence on "Urban Sprawl" is Unclear 10 (1999).) ("experts and much of the research agree that federal spending by the Department of Transportation and for the Interstate Highway System...supported the expansion of metropolitan areas by increasing access to suburban locations").

[FN36]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 91; Clarence N. Stone, Regime Politics: Governing Atlanta, 1946-88 32-33 (University Press of Kansas 1989).

[FN37]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 91 (transportation plan intended "to improve access to the city's central business district"); Stone, supra note 36, at 32 (to "preserve the central business district as a hub of economic activity...business leaders concluded, it would be necessary to link downtown with the suburbs by means of expressways").

[FN38]. See Allen, supra note 16, at 32-33, 69.

[FN39]. I use the term "white flight" because in the 1960s Atlantans who moved to suburbia were in fact disproportionately white. See Stone, supra note 36, at 77 (city lost whites during 1960s); Allen, supra note 16, at 163 (city gained blacks while losing whites during 1960s). But in recent decades, blacks have followed suit. See Cashin, supra note 8, at 741-42.

[FN40]. See Stone, supra note 36, at 77 (statistics re loss of whites); cf. Kelly Simmons & Dan Chapman, Sentenced to Commute, Atlanta J. Const., July 5, 2000 at D1 ("shopping centers and commuters followed new roads, particularly the interstates, starting in the 1950s"). Because the city of Atlanta was so heavily black by 1970, additional annexations were politically impossible: white suburbanites successfully fought any proposals to annex additional suburbs to the city. See Allen, supra note 16, at 147 (in 1966, voters in Sandy Springs, an unincorporated suburb, rejected annexation by Atlanta by 3-1 margin).

[FN41]. See supra note 38.

[FN42]. See Allen, supra note 16, at 199 (migrants followed I-75 to Cobb County, and I-85 to other two counties). Although metropolitan Atlanta contains twenty counties, the majority of the region's residents live in these three counties and in Fulton County (which contains the city of Atlanta and numerous suburbs). See 2001 Abstract, supra note 6, at 896 (listing county populations); infra note 73 (just under half of Fulton County population within city of Atlanta).

[FN43]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 23 (construction of highways during 1950s and 1960s accelerated dispersal of industry to suburbs, causing "serious decline in the market for industrial space in and around the downtown area").

[FN44]. Alfred R. Light, Bush v. Gore- Georgia Lived it Before: Pickrick and the Warren Court, 18 Ga. St. U. L. Rev. 449, 467-68 (2001) (discussing 1961 Atlanta mayoral election).

[FN45]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 69. Before Allen was mayor, he was president of the Atlanta Chamber of Commerce. Id. at 88.

[FN46]. Id. at 88.

[FN47]. Jim Auchmutey, The Perimeter at 25 Years: The Road We Love to Hate, Atlanta J. Const., May 9, 1995, at E1. Plans for I-285 were first unveiled in the mid-1950s. See Allen, supra note 16, at 69.

[FN48]. See David Beasley, Northlake/I-285 Area Has Matured Gracefully, Atlanta J. Const., Nov. 17, 1997, at E10, (describing one suburban office submarket as follows: "A new perimeter highway opened in 1969, transforming the LaVista Road intersection from sleepy suburbia to major retail center"); Hannah Kamenetsky, Trying to Save Clogged "Strip": Architect Must Please Residents and Retailers with Revitalization Plan, Atlanta J. Const., July 24, 1994, at G1 (suburban Sandy Springs "was woods and farmhouses until the 1960s, when I-285 opened it up to commercial development").

[FN49]. See Auchmutey, supra note 47.

[FN50]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 14, 18-19 (describing districts).

[FN51]. See Stone, supra note 36, at 250.

[FN52]. See Allen, supra note 16, at 199.

[FN53]. See Stone, supra note 36, at 82 (citation omitted).

[FN54]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 19-20 (describing Buckhead), 14 (map showing Buckhead's location vis-a-vis downtown and suburbs).

[FN55]. Although the Buckhead expressway was built to link Buckhead with a suburban road known as Georgia 400, the extension of this highway through Buckhead was sometimes colloquially referred to as "Georgia 400 extension." See, e.g., Stone, supra note 36, at 123 (using term); Keating, supra note 2, at 85 (highway would in fact link Buckhead with Georgia 400). Before the new highway was built, Georgia 400 ended at I-285 and did not extend into the city of Atlanta. See Stone, supra note 37, at 124 (Georgia 400 "connect[ed] the Buckhead area with the perimeter highway to the north").

[FN56]. See Stone, supra note 37, at 124.

[FN57]. See Stone, supra note 36, at 124 (noting that Georgia 400 would link Buckhead with I-285, and predicting that highway would stimulate development in northern suburbs).

[FN58]. Id. at 32.

[FN59]. See Stone, supra note 36, at 124 (report by Georgia Power Company asserted that highway would link Buckhead with northern suburbs).

[FN60]. Id. at 122 (admission "off the record").

[FN61]. Jim Newton, City Vote Clears Way for Work on Georgia 400: Opponents of Extension Vow to Continue Battle in Court, Atlanta J. Const., May 16, 1989, at A01. Cf. Keating, supra note 2, at 85 (noting that City Council approval required for highway to open).

[FN62]. Mike Morris, "Essential" Traffic Corridor was 41 Years in the Making, Atlanta J. Const., July 2, 1993, at F5.

[FN63]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 19; see also Tony Wilbert, UPS Unit Joins Corporate Exodus to Alpharetta, Atlanta J. Const., Feb. 14, 2001, at E1 (because of "easy access to Georgia 400", a "string of companies [moved] to Alpharetta from areas such as Buckhead" because executives "moved their offices close[r] to their homes").

[FN64]. William A. McGeveran Jr., ed., The World Almanac and Book of Facts 2002 at 397 (Roswell grew from 47,986 people to 79,334; Alpharetta grew from 13,002 people to 34,854).

[FN65]. See 2001 Abstract, supra note 6, at 35 (city population increased from 394,000 to 416,000 during 1990s).

[FN66]. Id. (city's 2000 population was lower than its pre-1980s population).

[FN67]. See Stone, supra note 36, at 133 ("the city's governing coalition has used public authority to connect the central business district with a growing and spreading hinterland"). Georgia's state government followed similar policies. See Keating, supra note 2, at 196 (Department of Transportation responded to traffic congestion with "constant expansions of the region's highway system").

[FN68]. Dick Williams, Other Voices: Part-Time Pay For Full-Time Government, Atlanta J. Const., May 4, 1996, at A10.

[FN69]. Keating, supra note 2, at 109. See supra notes 17-20 and accompanying text (describing weakness of downtown Atlanta as commercial center and after-dark destination)

[FN70]. See supra notes 20-22 and accompanying text (discussing absence of public transit in Atlanta suburbs).

[FN71]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 115 (citation omitted). At that time, Atlanta had bus service provided by a private company, but no intracity rail service. Id. at 218 n. 3.

[FN72]. Id. at 88.

[FN73]. Fulton County is both urban and suburban. About 381,000 of the county's 816,000 residents live in the city of Atlanta, and the rest live in surrounding suburbs. See McGeveran, supra note 64, at 425 (Fulton County had just over 816,000 residents in 2000, and Atlanta is its county seat); 2001 Abstract, supra note 6, at 35 (city of Atlanta had 416,000 residents in 2000); Stacy Shelton & Julie B. Hairston, City Folks Want Either Out or In Taxes spur cry to bolt Atlanta or link to Fulton, June 3, 2001, at F1 (35,000 City of Atlanta live in DeKalb County rather than in Fulton County).

[FN74]. Shelton & Julie B. Hairston, supra note 74 (35,000 City of Atlanta live in DeKalb County); McGeveran, supra note 65, at 425 (DeKalb County has just over 665,000 residents).

[FN75]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 115.

[FN76]. Id. at 127.

[FN77]. Id. at 113.

[FN78]. See Cox, supra note 22, at Ch. 1.

[FN79]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 115 (describing system first proposed by regional planning commission), 118, 128 (Gwinnett, Clayton and Cobb Counties rejected MARTA service); see also Sheryll D. Cashin, Survey, City Making: Building Communities Without Building Walls, by Gerald E. Frug, 98 Mich. L. Rev. 1704, 1722 (2000) ("the predominantly white outer counties long opposed expansion of MARTA, Atlanta's rail transport system, because of their fear of a connection to the predominantly black central city"); Orlyn O. Lockard, III, Solving the "Tragedy": Transportation, Pollution and Regionalism in Atlanta, 19 Va. Envtl. L.J. 161, 179-80 (2000) ("MARTA has not been extended from Fulton and DeKalb, counties with large minority populations, into other counties.... It has been repeatedly argued that suburban residents' desires to prevent minority residents from the urban core from gaining access to the suburban counties are to blame for the lack of a coherent, regional transportation planning system in Atlanta").

[FN80]. Cobb County began to operate a separate bus system in 1989, and Gwinnett and Clayton's bus systems (which are also separate from MARTA) opened in 2001. See Staff, County's Transit System Rolls Today, Atlanta J. Const., Nov. 5, 2001 at JJ1 (noting that Cobb County's system had opened 12 years earlier, Clayton County's system was a month old, and that Gwinnett launched system on day of story). The suburban bus systems are quite small: for example, Clayton County's system began with two bus routes, and Gwinnett County's with only three--despite the fact that Clayton County has over 200,000 inhabitants and Gwinnett over half a million. See McGeveran, supra note 64, at 425 (population figures); Joey Ledford, Piece By Piece, Regional Transit Becomes a Reality, Atlanta J. Const., October 28, 2001 at E5 (noting number of routes).

[FN81]. Kelly Simmons, Census Finds Metro Area In A Jam, Atlanta J. Const., Nov. 21, 2001, at A1 (citing Census Bureau estimate that 4% of metro Atlanta commuters use public transit).

[FN82]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 123; see also Stone, supra note 36, at 101 (population density lower in Atlanta than in most other cities with intracity rail); 2001 Abstract, supra note 6, at 35-37 (Atlanta had only 3161 people per square mile in 2000, less than majority of cities with over 400,000 people); Cox, supra note 18 (Atlanta suburbs also less densely populated than those of other cities).

[FN83]. Keating, supra note 2, at 123.

[FN84]. Id. at 124.

[FN85]. Id. at 129.

[FN86]. Id. at 125 (MARTA's initial financing scheme drafted by biracial group of business leaders); see also Stone, supra note 36, at 101 ("Atlanta's business elite remained centrally involved in promoting MARTA").

[FN87]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 114, 129.

[FN88]. Id. at 129-30; see also David Pendered, MARTA Aims to Help Shape Development, Atlanta J. Const., Oct. 19, 1998 at E1 (study underwritten by Georgia State University showed that "MARTA had no significant impact in the 1980s on the way the Atlanta region had grown...developers chose to build in areas close to highways the state Department of Transportation widened").

[FN89]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 131.

[FN90]. Id. at 133.

[FN91]. Id. at 132.

[FN92]. Id. at 22.

[FN93]. See supra note 22 and accompanying text (most suburban jobs inaccessible to transit-dependent city poor).

[FN94]. See supra notes 11-12, 15-16 and accompanying text. But cf. Sohmer & Lang, supra note 15, at 5-6 (noting that downtown regained population in 1990s).

[FN95]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 91.

[FN96]. Id. at 91-92.

[FN97]. Id. at 92.

[FN98]. Id. at 91; see also Lisa A. Kelly, Race and Place: Geographic and Transcendent Community in the Post-Shaw Era, 49 Vand. L. Rev. 227, 294 n. 217 (1996) ("In Atlanta, urban policy planners used highway design and construction to regulate black mobility and residential patterns").

[FN99]. See Stone, supra note 36, at 38 (defining "urban renewal" as "federal financial assistance for locally planned and executed redevelopment projects" under which land was often acquired by cities through eminent domain and sold to developers); cf. Lewyn, supra note 2, at 310-11 (describing history of federal urban renewal program). Although urban renewal was a nationwide program, id., Atlanta displaced residents more readily than (for example) the city of Baltimore. See Stone, supra note 36, at 162, 176.

[FN100]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 92. The city has two north-south expressways (I-75 and I-85) but near downtown they merge into one highway. Id. at 90.

[FN101]. Id. at 92.

[FN102]. See Allen, supra note 16, at 131 (in 1963 Atlanta voters approved bond referendum allocating $9 million for new civic center).

[FN103]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 103-05.

[FN104]. Id. at 104.

[FN105]. Id. at 107.

[FN106]. Id. at 109.

[FN107]. Id. at 108. Even outside downtown, the city sometimes sought to move blacks away from white areas. Id. at 44-45, 46-48 (describing numerous examples of elimination of black neighborhoods by city and county governments).

[FN108]. Id. at 109.

[FN109]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 93 (estimating that 68,000 Atlantans were displaced by highways and urban renewal); see also Stone, supra note 36, at 202 (estimating 67,000 Atlantans displaced); Allen, supra note 16, at 162 ("By one calculation, some 75,000 black Atlantans had been swept out of their homes").

[FN110]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 93 (estimating that between 19,000 and 22,000 households displaced).

[FN111]. See Stone, supra note 36, at 250 (city had 331,000 residents in 1950).

[FN112]. About 95% of the people displaced by redevelopment and highways, or at least 63,000 people, were black. See Keating, supra note 2, at 93. In 1950, 121,295 Atlantans were black. Bureau of the Census, Census of Population: 1950, Characteristics of the Population: Part 11, Georgia at 11-64 (1952) (city had 54,905 black males, and 66,380 black females). Thus, at least 51.9% of Atlanta's blacks (63,000 of 121,295) were displaced by urban renewal - and perhaps over 60% if one accepts Allen's higher estimate of the number of blacks displaced. Allen, supra note 16, at 162 (75,000 black Atlantans displaced).

[FN113]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 93.

[FN114]. Id. at 104 (Mayor Allen knew that after Buttermilk Bottoms was razed, its "displaced black families would be seeking housing in nearby white neighborhoods"); Allen, supra note 16, at 93 (blacks moved into white neighborhoods because "[u]rban renewal was wiping out slums and displacing thousands of families without providing replacement homes" and "[n]ew highways were cutting through parts of existing black neighborhoods").

[FN115]. Allen, supra note 16, at 199 (noting Atlanta whites' desire to move away from blacks); see also Stone, supra note 37, at 41 ("Nonaffluent whites on the southside and, as displacement mounted, on the eastside paid the main social costs of rapid racial turnover"). In fact, Mayor Hartsfield appointed a "housing coordinator" to regulate which neighborhoods would stay white and which would undergo a "conversion to black." Allen, supra note 16, at 92.

[FN116]. See Stone, supra note 36, at 86-87 (emphasis in original).

[FN117]. See Allen, supra note 16, at 198 ("Blacks now lived to the west, south and east of downtown Atlanta, as if holding the central business district in a cupped hand.").

[FN118]. See Sohmer & Lang, supra note 15, at 8.

[FN119]. Carrie Teegardin, Poor Areas Rich in Tickets, Atlanta J. Const., July 18, 1993 at D1 (30303 is downtown zip code); See Haines & Company, Criss Cross Haines 2001 Directory: Atlanta, Georgia City at 1 (zip code 30303 has third lowest household income, and second highest percentage of households earning under $10,000, among 25 Atlanta zip codes); id. at 675, 787-89 (same zip code includes many of state's governmental offices and law firms);

[FN120]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 52. Other municipalities require that individual apartments be unusually large. Id. at 51 (some suburban cities prohibit apartments with under 1000 square feet).

[FN121]. H.M. Cauley, Neighborhood of the Week, Atlanta J. Const., March 2, 1997, at H8, ("two-acre zoning" common in Buckhead); H.M. Cauley, New Home Communities: Close-in Communities Command Top Dollar, Atlanta J. Const., February 23, 1997 at H26 ("30327 area of Buckhead north of West Paces Ferry Road...[is] a neighborhood where two-acre zoning can support high-priced homes.").

[FN122]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 52. In fact, some Atlanta-area counties have 3- and 5-acre minimum lot sizes. Id.

[FN123]. Arthur C. Nelson, Exclusionary Practices and Urban Sprawl in Metropolitan Atlanta, 17 Ga. St. U. L. Rev. 1087, 1089 (2001).

[FN124]. See Keating, supra note 2, at 51-53 (suggesting that racial and economic exclusion is, in fact, the purpose of low-density zoning). Because Atlanta-area blacks are poorer than whites, id. at 37-40, zoning laws that exclude low-income renters and buyers disproportionately affect blacks. See Rolf Pendall, Local Land Use Regulation and the Chain of Exclusion, 66 J. Am. Plan. Ass'n 125142 (2000) (surveying localities in 25 largest U.S. metropolitan areas and finding that "low-density-only zoning, which restricts residential densities to fewer than eight dwelling units per acre, consistently reduced rental housing; this, in turn, limited the number of Black and Hispanic residents"); Nelson, supra note 114, at 1096.

[FN125]. Nelson, supra note 124, at 1095 ("low density housing is normally associated with greater dependency on the automobile"); see also Lewyn, supra note 18, at 285 (same).

[FN126]. John McCosh, Atlanta Building a New Approach, Atlanta J. Const., May 15, 2000, at E1 (making point, and noting that "[p]lanners point to the area surrounding this station as falling far short of its development potential").

[FN127]. See Allen, supra note 16, at 147 (describing Sandy Springs as an "unincorporated white enclave just north of Atlanta").

[FN128]. See Committee for Sandy Springs, Sandy Springs - Our Future City, http://www.sandysprings.net/city.html (last visited Dec. 20, 2002); Tony Wilbert, Mass Transit Draws IRS to Sandy Springs, Atlanta J. Const., May 31, 2001 at G1.

[FN129]. See Cheryl Crabb, "Smart Growth" Plans Near MARTA Stations Draw Opposition, Atlanta J. Const., August 19, 1999, at JH1.

[FN130]. See Tinah Saunders, Plan For Towers at North Springs Still in Dispute, Atlanta J. Const., July 5, 2001 at JH1 (developer originally proposed "850,000 square feet of space"); Sandy Eckstein, Sandy Springs Project OK'ed, Atlanta J. Const., August 2, 2001 at F3 (county approved "210,000 square feet of office space; 56,000 square feet of retail"). Cf. McCosh, supra note 126 (other transit-oriented developments have inspired opposition from neighbors).

[FN131]. Keating, supra note 2, at 210.

[FN132]. Id.

[FN133]. See supra notes 9-10 and accompanying text.

[FN134]. See Lewyn, supra note 2, at 339 n.283.

[FN135]. See Reed v. Rhodes, 1 F. Supp. 2d 705, 738 (N.D. Ohio 1998) ("children reared in lower socioeconomic status [households] tend to be less prepared for school which ultimately impacts on the child's achievements"); Lewyn, supra note 2, at 322-25 (discussing relationship between poverty and "bad schools" in more detail). Atlanta's school-related white flight has also been caused by factors beyond the control of local government, such as the federal courts' desegregation orders. See Michael Lewyn, The Courts v. The Cities, 25 Urb. Law 453 (1993) (describing Supreme Court desegregation doctrine); Allen, supra note 16, at 143-44 (describing white flight that resulted from Atlanta school desegregation plan; for example, one school had 470 white children on the last Friday of January 1965, and after school board announced that school would be integrated, only 7 white children present on following Monday).

[FN136]. See Lewyn, supra note 2, at 336 n.260 (citations omitted).

[FN137]. Allen, supra note 16, at 224.

Posted by lewyn at 3:03 PM EST
my University of Colorado L. Rev. piece
74 U. Colo. L. Rev. 651

*651 TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY PLANNING AND THE CONSTITUTION


Michael Lewyn [FNa1]

Introduction
The American Planning Association (APA), a nationwide organization of land use planners, [FN1] recently published the "Growing Smart [FN2] Legislative Guidebook" (hereinafter *652 "Guidebook") [FN3] containing over 1,450 pages [FN4] of model laws governing zoning and other land use-related issues. "Property rights" activists and some business groups [FN5] vigorously attack the Guidebook because of its pro-regulatory positions on a variety of issues. [FN6] For example, the libertarian Heartland Institute [FN7] describes the Guidebook as a "refutation of the American tradition of individual property rights." [FN8] Similarly, *653 twenty-one members of Congress wrote Housing and Urban Development (HUD) Secretary Mel Martinez urging him to attack the Guidebook on the grounds that it "would trample the rights of private property owners by seizing their land without the just compensation that our Constitution requires." [FN9] The most detailed criticisms of the Guidebook come from a group known as Defenders of Property Rights (DPR), [FN10] a conservative public interest legal foundation that represents landowners in disputes with government agencies. [FN11] DPR suggests that the Guidebook violates the First, Fourth, Fifth, *654 Tenth, and Fourteenth Amendments [FN12] and its executive director recently called the Guidebook a "federal zoning code." [FN13]
This Article focuses on the question of whether the Guidebook's model statutes, if enacted by a state legislature, would violate the federal Constitution under existing case law. [FN14] Part I of this Article discusses the history of the Guidebook, explaining why and how it was drafted. Part II analyzes the Guidebook's constitutionality under the First, Fourth, Fifth, Tenth, and Fourteenth Amendments and concludes that no part of the Guidebook is unconstitutional on its face under existing case law. The Article concludes that as a general matter, the Guidebook's most controversial provisions (and thus state laws patterned on those provisions) are constitutional on their face if correctly interpreted.


I. Background: The History of Model Land Use Laws
The Guidebook is not the first attempt to standardize state zoning laws. To date, the most ambitious and successful attempts [FN15] to standardize land use regulation consist of two *655 model planning and zoning statutes drafted in the 1920s, the Standard State Zoning Enabling Act (SZEA) [FN16] and the Standard City Planning Enabling Act (SPEA). [FN17] These statutes continue to dominate most states' land use laws [FN18] and the Guidebook seeks to cure their defects. [FN19]

A. In the Beginning: SZEA and SPEA
Model zoning statutes are almost as old as zoning itself. Los Angeles enacted the first American zoning ordinance in 1909. [FN20] Just a dozen years later, the federal Commerce Department created an advisory committee on zoning and drafted the first version of the SZEA. [FN21] In 1926, the Commerce Department drafted a revised version of the SZEA. [FN22] Adopted in some form by all fifty states, [FN23] this revised SZEA, in modified *656 form, is still in effect in forty-seven states. [FN24] The Commerce Department's interest in zoning arose from Secretary of Commerce Herbert Hoover's concerns that without zoning, cities would lack adequate public infrastructure to serve their growing populations and that property values in residential neighborhoods would be threatened by the growth of incompatible uses. [FN25]
The SZEA included provisions granting local governments power to enact zoning ordinances dividing cities into districts, as well as language setting forth procedures for establishing, enforcing, and amending zoning laws, and for granting variances from those laws. [FN26] After states enacted SZEA-type laws authorizing municipal zoning, local governments began to enact SZEA-inspired zoning ordinances that courts generally upheld. [FN27] Today, Houston is the only large city without zoning. [FN28]
In 1928, the Department of Commerce drafted SPEA, a statute intended to complement the SZEA. [FN29] This model statute authorized local governments to appoint a planning commission [FN30] and required the commission to create a master plan that includes, among other things, the recommended locations and character of public improvements such as streets, playgrounds, and open spaces. [FN31] SPEA proved to be far less *657 influential than SZEA, [FN32] however, because the SPEA did not give planning commissions the power to ensure that zoning laws conformed to the master plan. [FN33] In fact, the SPEA limits municipal power over private land use by implying that a master plan is to be taken into account by the municipality only to the extent that it governs the construction of public facilities. [FN34]

B. History of the Guidebook
The call for a new model land use code originated from two sources at about the same time. [FN35] In 1991, a HUD advisory commission on barriers to affordable housing recommended that HUD "work with government and private-industry groups, such as the American Bar Association, the American Planning Association . . . and others to develop consensus-based model codes and statutes for use by State and local governments." [FN36] Specifically, the commission recommended, inter alia, a new model state zoning enabling act. [FN37] Also in 1991, the APA decided to create a task force to draft new model planning and zoning enabling legislation based on the group's "concern [] about the number of bills to [reform] planning and land development control being introduced in state legislatures without an overall body of evaluative research to offer *658 guidance." [FN38] The task force decided to draft a model code setting forth alternative approaches to land use regulation rather than mandating a one-size-fits-all code for all states. [FN39] The APA sought funding from HUD and the Henry Jackson Foundation [FN40] in 1992 and 1993, [FN41] finally receiving funding in 1994. [FN42]
At the request of HUD, the APA created an advisory board, known as the "directorate", comprised primarily of representatives of APA and of numerous national associations representing state and local government officials. [FN43] The directorate also included three private sector members-at-large: the executive director of the International Municipal Lawyers Association, [FN44] an attorney for the Environmental Law Institute designated as a representative of environmentalists, [FN45] and a home builder [FN46] designated as representative of the "Built Environment" [FN47]--that is, "home builders, office and industrial developers, real estate agents, general contractors, road builders, engineers, architects, and others who are generally *659 classed as the built environment." [FN48] The directorate met twice a year during the duration of the project and succeeded in reaching a consensus on most issues. [FN49] In addition, the APA began an outreach program, mailing a semi-annual project newsletter to numerous interest groups and maintaining a project website. As a result, the APA received hundreds of pages of comments and recommendations [FN50] from environmental groups, organizations representing builders and developers, organizations representing the sign industry, historic preservation groups, and numerous other organizations. [FN51] The APA later adopted eighty-five percent of those suggestions in some form. [FN52]
The APA released an interim edition of the Guidebook in 1996. This first edition focused on state and regional planning, as well as affordable housing. [FN53] A second edition replaced the first in 1998 [FN54] and was more extensive, containing model legislation on local land use planning, state review and approval of local land use plans, and integration of local land use plans with state environmental law. [FN55] Finally, the APA published the final edition of the Guidebook in 2002. [FN56]

C. The Guidebook: Why It Exists, What It Does
The final edition of the Guidebook explains in its preface that SZEA and the SPEA "are incapable of meeting the challenges of the twenty-first century." [FN57] Specifically, the Guidebook asserts that these 1920s model statutes:
*660 1. Fail to discuss the states' role in land use regulation because at that time land use planning was generally a local, rather than a state, activity. [FN58] By contrast, state legislatures now take an active role in land use regulation in order to ensure uniformity and to address issues spilling across jurisdictional boundaries; [FN59]
2. Do not address environmental issues such as the value of preserving vacant, developable land or the environmental consequences of the form and relative compactness of metropolitan areas; [FN60]
3. Provide inadequate opportunities for citizen participation in the zoning process; [FN61] and
4. Fail to consider the courts' increased scrutiny of land use regulation in recent decades. [FN62] The Guidebook contains fifteen chapters, covering the topics addressed in the earlier editions and adding detailed discussion of zoning, subdivision regulation, smart growth legislation, state biodiversity conservation plans, environmental protection, procedures for siting controversial state facilities, development oriented towards public transit, development moratoria, judicial review, public records of plans and regulations, and a wide variety of other issues. [FN63] Accompanying the Guidebook is a User Manual that, by means of checklists and case studies, seeks to help government officials use the Guidebook and in particular, "to tailor a program of statutory reform that will meet the unique needs of their state." [FN64] The User Manual also instructs readers that each chapter in the Guidebook follows the following format: first a chapter outline identifying the major topics in the *661 chapter, then an introduction setting forth a general discussion of the subject matter covering and summarizing its contents, then commentary to individual model statutes, and finally draft statutory language and alternatives. [FN65]
What the Guidebook does not do is directly address the federal role in land use regulation; that issue is left to Congress. [FN66] Instead, the Guidebook seeks to guide state and local land use law.


II. Analysis: The Guidebook and the Constitution
Guidebook critics allege the following constitutional infirmities in the Guidebook's model statutes:
1. The Guidebook's model sign regulation law violates the First Amendment by restricting businesses' right to advertise; [FN67]
2. Guidebook provisions regarding zoning-related searches violate the Fourth Amendment; [FN68]
*662 3. A wide variety of Guidebook proposals violate the Fifth Amendment, [FN69] especially the "Takings Clause" of that Amendment; [FN70]
4. The Guidebook's model statutes violate the Tenth Amendment by increasing federal power over land use; [FN71] and
5. The Guidebook's model statute governing design districts violates the Equal Protection Clause [FN72] of the Fourteenth Amendment. [FN73] Each of these issues will be addressed in turn.

A. The Guidebook and the First Amendment
Section 8-201(2)(h) of the Guidebook states that local zoning laws may regulate "location, period of display, size, height, spacing, movement and aesthetic features of signs, including the locations at which signs may and may not be placed." [FN74] This statute closely resembles Hawaii's statute allowing counties to "adopt ordinances regulating billboards *663 and outdoor advertising devices not prohibited by [state law]" [FN75] and in particular to "[r]egulate the size, manner of construction, color, illumination, location, and appearance of any class of billboard or outdoor advertising device." [FN76]
Other states' laws give local governments even more leeway to regulate outdoor advertising. [FN77] For example, Maine law not only limits the number, [FN78] location, [FN79] and height [FN80] of on-premise signs, [FN81] but also provides that state law "shall not supersede the provisions of any other statute, regulation, ordinance or resolution, the requirements of which are more strict than those of this chapter and not inconsistent therewith." [FN82] Vermont and Rhode Island likewise allow local governments to enact sign regulations stricter than those implemented by state government, without limiting local discretion as to the nature of such regulations. [FN83] While the Guidebook limits municipal sign regulation to "location, period *664 of display, size, height, spacing, movement and aesthetic features of signs," [FN84] the laws of Maine, Rhode Island, and Vermont do not include even this bit of protection for landowners. Rather, all three states apparently give local governments unlimited power to regulate billboards.
Nevertheless, DPR argues that the Guidebook's model statute violates the First Amendment, [FN85] primarily because it "allows local governments virtually unlimited control over the ability of a businessperson to advertise in his or her place of business." [FN86] In other words, DPR asserts that by giving local governments power to regulate on-premise signs, Section 8- 201(2)(h) violates landowners' First Amendment right to advertise their businesses. [FN87] This argument is unlikely to prevail in court because the most relevant state and federal district court decisions generally uphold the government's right to regulate on-premise signs. In Central Hudson Gas & Electric Corp. v. Public Service Commission of New York, [FN88] and more recently in Lorillard Tobacco Co. v. Reilly, [FN89] the Supreme Court held that under the First Amendment, even truthful advertising concerning lawful activity may nevertheless be regulated if (1) a "substantial" government interest justifies regulation, [FN90] (2) the regulation at issue "directly advances the *665 governmental interest asserted," [FN91] and (3) the regulation is "not more extensive than is necessary to serve that interest." [FN92] Later decisions make clear that traffic safety and aesthetic rationales for on-premise sign regulation [FN93] are "substantial" within the meaning of Central Hudson. [FN94] Thus, only the last two prongs of Central Hudson create controversy in cases involving regulation of on-premise signs.
As a rule, "[r]easonable restrictions governing size, setbacks, lighting, color, placement, orientation, design, number, height, spacing, or otherwise regulating the manner of advertising devices, will be upheld." [FN95] Although local governments generally regulate on-premise commercial signs less strictly than off-premise commercial signs, [FN96] courts usually uphold zoning ordinances regulating on-premise signs under the Central Hudson test. For example, in Brewster v. City of Dallas, [FN97] the plaintiff asserted that a zoning ordinance restricting "the location of signs . . . [and] the size, luminance and movement of signs; their projection from building walls; the size and number of words they may contain, and the number of signs at a given location" [FN98] violated the First Amendment as it pertained to on-premise commercial signs. [FN99] The court rejected the plaintiff's First Amendment claim, *666 holding that, as required by Central Hudson, [FN100] the city's ordinance (1) directly advanced the city's legitimate interests [FN101] and (2) reached no further than necessary to satisfy those interests. [FN102] As to the former issue, the court held that the ordinance directly advanced the city's substantial interests in "promoting traffic safety, communications efficiency, and landscape quality and preservation." [FN103] The court based that conclusion on the city's finding that "the restrictions promoted efficiency by ensuring that persons exposed to signs are not so overwhelmed by the number of messages presented that they cannot find the information they seek," [FN104] and on the absence of evidence contradicting the city's finding that its ordinance promoted traffic safety [FN105] and created "some positive aesthetic effect." [FN106] As to the latter issue, the court found that the city's zoning ordinance "reach[ed] no further than necessary to accomplish its objectives" [FN107] because it "merely regulates, without prohibiting, on-site advertising" [FN108] and was "content neutral." [FN109] The ordinance was thus probably constitutional [FN110] *667 because "[it] does not select the messages the public can see; it merely regulates the non-communicative aspects of signs. Sign owners can still display their messages; the only change is in the way they can display them." [FN111]
In some respects, Brewster is directly on point. Just as the Guidebook allows regulation of signs' location, size, height, and other non-communicative aspects, [FN112] the ordinance upheld in Brewster regulated signs' location, size, and similar aesthetic features. [FN113] It follows that if Brewster is still good law, Section 8-201(2)(h) of the Guidebook is clearly constitutional. It could be argued, however, that the Brewster court erred in one important respect. The Brewster court deferred to the city's judgment that its zoning laws directly advanced its goals of safety, aesthetic values, and efficiency, [FN114] based on that court's assumption that "as plaintiff, Brewster bears the burden of proof." [FN115] But Supreme Court precedent holds that "the party seeking to uphold a restriction on commercial speech carries the burden of justifying it." [FN116] Thus, Brewster does not answer the question of whether, given that the government has the burden of proof, Section 8-201(2)(h) and similar regulations are constitutional.
To meet its burden of justifying a restriction on commercial speech, a state or local government need not supply the court with "a surfeit of background information." [FN117] Instead, the Supreme Court "[permits] litigants to justify speech restrictions by references to studies and anecdotes pertaining to different locales altogether or even . . . to justify restrictions based solely on history, consensus, and simple common sense." [FN118] In other words, a state or municipality can *668 constitutionally regulate commercial speech, such as signs, as long as it gives the court some reason to believe that the sign restrictions at issue do in fact advance aesthetics, traffic safety, or some other public goal.
Two California cases suggest that where government seeks to regulate on-premise signs, its burden of proof is easily met. In Rodriguez v. Solis, [FN119] a city denied an auto dealer's request for a permit to erect on-premise signs within fifty feet of a freeway "on the ground that the signs would not be compatible with the landscaped environment of Freeway 41 [the freeway in question]." [FN120] Thus, the question presented was "whether a municipality can constitutionally restrict a property owner from erecting an onsite business sign oriented towards a landscaped freeway." [FN121] The plaintiff argued that the city "failed to establish that the ordinance advances aesthetic interests." [FN122] Put another way, the plaintiff asserted that the city failed to meet its burden of proving that the city's regulation directly advanced a substantial government interest (as required by Central Hudson). [FN123] The court did not deny that the city had the burden of proof, but nevertheless found that "[b]y characterizing signs along Freeway 41 as visual blight and then taking measures to limit or prohibit such signs, the city council took steps to advance the governmental interest of controlling that visual blight." [FN124] In other words, the Rodriguez court held that because the city characterized plaintiff's on-premise signs as "visual blight," any regulation of those signs directly advanced the city's substantial [FN125] interest in controlling visual blight. So even if the city had the burden of showing that its regulations directly advanced its aesthetic interest, the city met this burden. The Rodriguez court went on to hold that the city satisfied the Central Hudson [FN126] Court's requirement that "the ordinance reaches no further than necessary to accomplish the city's objective." [FN127] In support of this conclusion, *669 the court pointed out that the city "has not banned all onsite billboards . . . . The only type of sign advertising disallowed is that which can be reasonably construed as contributing to visual blight." [FN128] Thus, Rodriguez suggests that as long as a city's restrictions on on-premise signs merely regulate "visual blight" rather than outlawing all onsite signs, such regulations are not overbroad under Central Hudson. It logically follows that the Guidebook's model statute (which also seeks to regulate rather than to eliminate on-premise signs) is also constitutional under Central Hudson.
The Rodriguez court relied partially on dicta from City of Indio v. Arroyo. [FN129] In Arroyo, the city sought to remove a mural painted on the location of a small convenience store on the ground that the mural was larger than allowed by the city's sign ordinance. [FN130] The court implicitly acknowledged that the municipality had the burden of proof, stating that if "the city could demonstrate, for example, that the mural posed a traffic hazard . . . then abatement would be proper." [FN131] The court further held that the city's ordinance was unconstitutionally overbroad because the mural was a noncommercial depiction of the owners' Mexican heritage rather than a commercial advertisement [FN132] and aesthetic judgments that might justify regulation of commercial speech could not justify suppression of such artistic speech. [FN133] But the court added in dicta, "[t]he city's interest in its esthetic environment is directly advanced by the ordinance's regulation of commercial speech. We have little doubt that if, for example, the Arroyos' wall advertised 'Cold Beer, Come Inside!' it could properly be regulated in the precise fashion contemplated with regard to the mural as it exists." [FN134] In other words, Arroyo states that the size of an on-premise sign or mural may be limited on aesthetic grounds--a proposition completely consistent with the Guidebook's position *670 that local governments may regulate the "size, height, spacing, movement and aesthetic features of signs." [FN135]
Both Arroyo and Rodriguez support the proposition that even if a municipality has the burden of justifying its regulations, it nevertheless may limit the size and location of on-premise commercial signs. It follows that under these cases, the Guidebook's model statute limiting the size, location, and other aesthetic features of on-premise signs does not violate the First Amendment.
It could be argued that In re Deyo [FN136] compels a contrary outcome. In Deyo, the owner of commercial office space challenged a city ordinance that "prohibited on-premise signs advertising the sale or lease of real estate." [FN137] The Vermont courts found that the ordinance was unconstitutional for two reasons. First, "by permitting other types of signs that are distracting to motorists, the traffic safety benefits of the ordinance were undermined." [FN138] Second, "the sign ordinance substantially limited property owners' ability to market their property because the alternatives available - listing with real estate agents or advertising in the classified section of newspapers - were less than satisfactory." [FN139] The law invalidated in Deyo completely prohibited on-site signs related to real estate transactions. By contrast, the Brewster and Rodriguez courts implicitly distinguished cases such as Deyo, by emphasizing that the ordinances at issue were constitutional because they "merely regulate[d], without prohibiting, on-site advertising." [FN140] In other words, Deyo held that a city government could not completely prohibit the erection of on-premise signs, whether for one type of business *671 or for all local businesses. Brewster and Rodriguez addressed an entirely different question: whether a city government could regulate on-premise signs, without prohibiting them, by regulating the size and location of such signs.
Section 8-201(2)(h) of the Guidebook resembles the ordinance upheld in Brewster rather than the ordinance struck down in Deyo. The Guidebook statute apparently does not allow local governments to prohibit on-premise signs altogether, either for all commercial enterprises or for one particular type of business. Instead, the Guidebook authorizes regulation of the "location, period of display, size, height, spacing, movement and aesthetic features of signs" [FN141]--just as the ordinance upheld in Brewster regulated "the location of signs" and "the size, luminance and movement of signs; their projection from building walls; the size and number of words they may contain, and the number of signs at a given location." [FN142]
One might argue that by allowing local governments to regulate the "location" of signs, the Guidebook in fact allows the prohibition of such signs because a zoning ordinance providing that "there shall be no advertising signs in city X" not only prohibits the erection of such signs but also regulates their location by excluding them from city X. But such an interpretation of the Guidebook is probably incorrect, for three reasons. First, if the Guidebook's authors intended to allow local governments to prohibit signs, they could have used the term "prohibit," which they did not do. Second, as noted above, the Brewster court interpreted an ordinance that regulated the "location" [FN143] of signs as an invitation to regulate signs rather than prohibiting them entirely. [FN144] It follows that the Guidebook should be similarly interpreted. Third, Supreme Court precedent holds that if "a statute is susceptible of two constructions, by one of which grave and doubtful *672 constitutional questions arise and by the other of which such questions are avoided, [the court's] duty is to avoid the latter." [FN145] So if lower courts can possibly interpret Section 8-201(2)(h) to authorize mere regulation of on-premise sign location and aesthetics rather than citywide [FN146] prohibitions of such signs, they will do so and thus uphold that statute and similarly worded state statutes against a First Amendment challenge.
Because no federal appellate case is on point, the constitutionality of local regulation of on-premise signs is not yet clear beyond all dispute. However, relevant district court and state cases hold that statutes that regulate the size, location, and similar aesthetic features of on-premise signs are consistent with the First Amendment. It follows that if Section 8-201(2)(h) is correctly interpreted to allow such regulation, it too is probably consistent with the First Amendment under existing case law. But any statute that seeks to outlaw on-premises signs is constitutionally questionable.

B. The Guidebook and the Fourth Amendment
The Fourth Amendment provides that persons' rights "against unreasonable searches and seizures, shall not be violated, and no Warrants shall issue, but upon probable cause, supported by Oath or affirmation, and particularly describing the place to be searched, and the persons or things to be seized." [FN147] The Fourth Amendment applies to both the federal government and to state and local governments [FN148] and its purpose is "to safeguard the privacy and security of individuals against arbitrary invasions by governmental officials." [FN149] As a general rule, "a search of private property without proper consent is 'unreasonable' unless it has been authorized by a valid search warrant." [FN150] Section 11-101 of the Guidebook *673 provides that a municipality may obtain a warrant to search a landowner's property [FN151] after proving to a court "that there is probable cause to believe that the property is not in compliance with land development regulations." [FN152] DPR asserts that Section 11-101 violates the Fourth Amendment's prohibition of "unreasonable searches and seizures" [FN153] because, inter alia, [FN154] that statute (1) does not require municipal inspectors to give landowners advance notice of searches, [FN155] (2) allows police officers to accompany zoning inspectors on searches, [FN156] and (3) allows local governments to act upon communications from any person. [FN157] Each of these contentions will be addressed in turn.
1. Notice
Section 11-101(7) of the Guidebook provides that local government officials "may notify or warn persons that they are or may be violating land development regulations" [FN158] before searching their property. The Guidebook's use of the word *674 "may" indicates that such notice is not mandatory--a proposition that, according to DPR, is contrary to the Fourth Amendment. [FN159] Two Supreme Court cases are highly relevant. In Camara v. Municipal Court, [FN160] the Supreme Court held that building inspectors must obtain search warrants in order to engage in housing-related administrative searches. [FN161] But under Camara, "there is no obligation on the inspector to give advance notice, or, if he is denied entry, to indicate his intention to return with a warrant, make the time of his return known in advance, or arrange a time convenient to the occupant." [FN162]
In Marshall v. Barlow's, Inc., [FN163] the Court extended Camara by holding that under the Fourth Amendment, agents of the Secretary of Labor must obtain search warrants in order to inspect employment facilities for safety hazards. [FN164] In support of this decision, the Court pointed out that a warrant requirement would not cripple the Labor Department's ability to perform surprise inspections because "warrants may be issued ex parte and executed without delay and without prior *675 notice, thereby preserving the element of surprise." [FN165] Thus, Barlow suggests that the Fourth Amendment allows government inspectors to search land "without prior notice." [FN166]
2. Police Searches and Administrative Searches
Section 11-101(4)(d) of the Guidebook provides that zoning inspectors "may be accompanied by one or more sworn officers of the [local] police department." [FN167] These officers "shall not participate in the inspection, and an entry and inspection pursuant to this paragraph shall not, by the mere presence of police officers pursuant to this paragraph, be considered to be a search by police officials." [FN168] The commentary to this provision explains that police officers "should accompany planning agency or code enforcement personnel only when it is believed there is a possibility of violence against the personnel in performance of their duties" [FN169] and may not participate in searches. [FN170] DPR complains that even though Section 11-104(4)(d) explicitly prohibits police officers from participating in zoning inspections, their mere presence creates a risk that the police might "surreptitiously gather evidence for possible criminal charges against a property owner." [FN171] Thus, the question presented is whether police officers may constitutionally accompany zoning inspectors on a search.
The case of Alexander v. City and County of San Francisco [FN172] is nearly on point. Alexander arose out of the following facts: City health inspectors visited a homeowner's residence in order to search the premises. [FN173] The homeowner shot at police officers who accompanied the inspectors and was in turn fatally shot. [FN174] The executor of the homeowner's estate sued the city, alleging that the officers violated the homeowner's Fourth Amendment rights because they "entered [the homeowner's house] for the purpose of arresting him, but *676 had only an administrative inspection warrant in their possession." [FN175] The trial court granted defendants' motion for summary judgment, but the Ninth Circuit reversed. [FN176] The court initially noted that "as an initial matter a forcible entry warrant provides a lawful basis for entry," [FN177] without making a distinction between police officers and health inspectors. Thus, Alexander suggests that a valid administrative warrant may justify entry by both administrative inspectors and police officers.
The court nevertheless went on to hold that summary judgment was inappropriate because "if in fact the officers' primary purpose in storming the house was to arrest [the homeowner] rather than to assist the health officials in executing the inspection warrant, then [the homeowner's] Fourth Amendment rights were violated." [FN178] It logically follows from this statement that if the officers' primary purpose was to assist the health officials rather than to make an arrest, no Fourth Amendment violation occurred. Thus, Alexander stands for the proposition that police officers may accompany zoning inspectors on searches if their goal is to protect the inspectors, but may not do so if their goal is to act as criminal investigators (i.e., to arrest landowners or perform searches that might lead to such arrests). Because the Guidebook allows police to pursue the former goal but not the latter, [FN179] its language accurately tracks that of Alexander and thus does not violate the Fourth Amendment.
3. Who Can Complain
Section 11-101(6) of the Guidebook provides that a municipality "may receive from any person informal communications alleging that a person or persons are or may be violating land development regulations . . . [and] may act upon communications as defined in this paragraph as it deems appropriate." [FN180] DPR complains that under this model statute, local governments may obtain inspection warrants based on *677 allegations "by anyone, such as neighbors, nearby businesses, or other 'interested citizens."' [FN181] It is well settled that even searches based on anonymous tips do not automatically violate the Fourth Amendment, both in the criminal context [FN182] and in the administrative context. [FN183] Thus, Section 11-101(6) presents no Fourth Amendment problem.

C. The Guidebook and the Fifth Amendment
The Fifth Amendment provides that no person may be "deprived of life, liberty or property without due process of law; nor shall private property be taken for public use, without just compensation." [FN184] Pursuant to the Due Process and Takings Clauses of that amendment, Guidebook critics attack the Guidebook's provisions regarding (1) development moratoria; [FN185] (2) design review districts; [FN186] (3) historic preservation; [FN187] (4) rezoning of existing land uses; [FN188] (5) local government approval of subdivisions; [FN189] (6) transferable development rights; [FN190] (7) criminal sanctions for violation of zoning laws; [FN191] (8) dedications of property in exchange for building permits; [FN192] and (9) amortization of nonconforming uses. [FN193] Each of these issues will be addressed in turn.
*678 1. Development Moratoria
a. The Guidebook's Rules
Eight states authorize local governments to impose development moratoria, which are temporary prohibitions on new development or on connection of newly developed property to publicly owned water and sewer lines. [FN194] Typically, moratoria are imposed when municipal officials are preparing an extensive amendment of land use regulations and seek to have pending requests for development considered under the new rules they wish to adopt [FN195] or when public facilities such as roads and sewers are not yet adequate to serve new development. [FN196]
Rather than adopting a one-size-fits-all provision on moratoria, Section 8- 604(3) of the Guidebook proposes three model state statutes. Alternative One allows moratoria (1) where development presents a "significant threat to the public health or safety or general welfare" [FN197] or (2) where a municipality is in the process of preparing or amending either a local comprehensive plan or land development regulations implementing a new or amended local comprehensive plan. [FN198] Alternative Two allows a moratorium in the situations listed in Alternative One [FN199] and also to prevent "a shortage or overburden of public facilities that would otherwise occur during the effective term of the moratorium or that is reasonably foreseeable as a result of any proposed or *679 anticipated development." [FN200] Alternative Three allows moratoria only to prevent the shortage or overburden of public facilities referred to in Alternative Two [FN201] or to prevent "a significant threat to the public health or safety." [FN202] Moratoria are limited to 180 days unless a municipality enacts extensions. [FN203] The Guidebook gives legislatures the option of further restricting moratoria in already-developed areas. [FN204]
b. Moratoria Are Constitutional . . .
The Supreme Court recently upheld a development moratorium in Tahoe-Sierra Preservation Council v. Tahoe Regional Planning Agency. [FN205] In Tahoe-Sierra, the question before the Court was whether "a moratorium on development imposed during the process of devising a comprehensive land-use plan constitutes a per se taking of property requiring compensation under the Takings Clause." [FN206] The Supreme Court flatly refused to ban moratoria, holding that "the extreme categorical rule that any deprivation of all economic use, no matter how brief, constitutes a compensable taking surely cannot be sustained." [FN207] Instead, the Court held that the constitutionality of moratoria, like the constitutionality of most other land use regulations not involving a physical occupation of property, [FN208] or elimination of the property's economic value, [FN209] is governed by the balancing test generally used to decide whether a government regulation constitutes an *680 unconstitutional taking. [FN210] Under this test, the courts weigh "the regulation's economic impact on the landowner, the extent to which the regulation interferes with reasonable investment-backed expectations, and the character of the government action." [FN211] Thus, Tahoe-Sierra bars any claim that development moratoria are always unconstitutional. [FN212]
c. But Not If They Are Permanent
However, under Tahoe-Sierra, a moratorium may be an unconstitutional taking if it is permanent rather than temporary. [FN213] DPR asserts that the Guidebook in fact endorses permanent moratoria, and is thus unconstitutional under Tahoe-Sierra, because it contains "no meaningful time limit for moratoria when the local government still perceives that a need for moratoria exists." [FN214] Section 8-604(5) of the Guidebook states that a moratorium's term "except as otherwise provided herein, shall not be more than [180] days." [FN215] Section 8-604(8) states that a local government "may extend an ordinance establishing a moratorium on the issuance of development permits for [only one or up to two] additional [180]-day *681 period[s]." [FN216] The existence of brackets in the Guidebook's language could be interpreted either to mean that local governments may adopt no more than two 180-day extensions or that legislatures may, by deleting these brackets, allow unlimited moratoria.
But the Guidebook's commentary clarifies this ambiguity, explaining that a "moratorium ordinance must state a duration for the moratoria not in excess of 180 days, but a moratorium may be extended by ordinance . . . An extension may not last over 180 days, and the Section provides for either only one extension or two at the adopting legislature's option." [FN217] Thus, the Guidebook's authors intended to limit moratoria to 180 days for an initial moratorium and 180 for each of two possible extensions. This yields a grand total of 540 days, a length of time contemplated by the Tahoe-Sierra Court's statement that "we could not possibly conclude that every delay of over one year is constitutionally unacceptable." [FN218] It follows that the Guidebook, if properly interpreted, authorizes temporary rather than permanent moratoria. Because temporary moratoria are constitutional, the Guidebook's moratorium provisions are constitutional as well.
2. Design Review and Historic Preservation
Design review regulations attempt to "promote community character by insuring that a certain *682 architectural style or styles are followed . . . or, in contrast, that architectural diversity is encouraged." [FN219] The former type of regulation seeks to ensure that new buildings are compatible with nearby buildings, while the latter type of regulation seeks to avoid monotony. [FN220] Historic preservation ordinances similarly seek to protect the character of neighborhoods, but are generally limited to districts "that may be associated with an important historic event or person or are representative of a certain architectural type or period." [FN221] Section 9-301 of the Guidebook authorizes both forms of regulation.
a. Design Review
Section 9-301 of the Guidebook authorizes local governments to designate "areas by ordinance as design review districts" [FN222]--areas with structures "united aesthetically by development or that, in the determination of the local legislative body, [have] the potential to be united aesthetically by development." [FN223] Within such areas, property owners must obtain a "certificate of appropriateness" [FN224] - a written decision by a local design review board that their development conforms with the design review ordinance [FN225] - for "all proposed development removing, destroying, adding, or altering exterior [and interior] architectural features of properties located in a . . . design review district." [FN226] Design review board decisions must be based on "standards of review to be applied . . . in reviewing applications for the certificate of appropriateness. These criteria shall include such matters as are consistent with the desired character of the exterior [and interior] architectural features of buildings and structures and their surroundings." [FN227] One Guidebook critic suggests that Section 9-301 violates the Fifth Amendment by giving government veto power over "changes to the interior or exterior of [a] business--a process involving layers of bureaucracy and subject to the personal opinions of government officials." [FN228]
*683 Both the United States Supreme Court and the majority of state courts allow government to regulate land use to promote aesthetic values. [FN229] Nevertheless, the Guidebook commentary itself concedes that design review ordinances may violate due process under case law invalidating such statutes as "an improper delegation of power or because they were unconstitutionally vague and thus it was difficult for a board to make a decision based on the standards in the ordinance." [FN230] *684 As a rule, a land use "ordinance is void for vagueness if it fails to give persons of ordinary intelligence fair notice that their contemplated conduct is proscribed by the ordinance" [FN231] and is an unconstitutional delegation of power to administrative agencies if it is not "accompanied by discernible standards, so that the delegatee's action can be measured for its fidelity to the legislative will." [FN232] In other words, both the "delegation doctrine" and the "vagueness doctrine" prohibit government from granting unlimited discretion to design review boards.
One might argue that Section 9-301 is unconstitutional under both doctrines because it does not establish substantive criteria to govern design review boards. But the Guidebook directs local governments to create such criteria by stating that a local "design review ordinance adopted pursuant to this Section shall include . . . standards of review to be applied by the historic preservation board and/or design review board in reviewing applications for the certificate of appropriateness." [FN233] In other words, if State X enacts a zoning enabling statute patterned on the Guidebook and a local zoning ordinance authorized by that section fails to include "standards of review to be applied by the . . . design review board," [FN234] the ordinance violates both Section 9-301 and the Due Process Clause. [FN235] *685 Therefore, Section 9-301 is not itself unconstitutional and a landowner who wishes to challenge a design review board decision on constitutional grounds should assert that the local ordinance authorizing that decision is unconstitutionally vague, rather than challenging the vagueness of the state law authorizing that ordinance.
Cases invalidating overly vague design review ordinances indirectly support this view; those cases invalidated local zoning laws, rather than attacking state zoning enabling statutes that authorized local governments to enact those laws. [FN236] And wisely so because if state enabling acts had to be as specific as a local ordinance must be in order to pass constitutional muster, states would have to micromanage local zoning boards by dictating what sort of building designs should be allowed and which should be forbidden. [FN237]
*686 b. Historic Preservation
Section 9-301 also authorizes historic preservation ordinances that designate areas as historic preservation districts and designate individual properties as historic landmarks. [FN238] If a property or district is so designated, "a certificate of appropriateness [must] be obtained from a historic preservation board for development affecting the . . . architectural features of all or specified proposed development therein." [FN239] A historic preservation board's decision as to issuance of such certificates must be governed by municipally enacted criteria dictating the "desired character of the exterior [and interior] architectural features of buildings and structures and their surroundings in a historic district . . . or on properties that have been designated as historic landmarks." [FN240]
Over time, all fifty states and over five hundred local governments enacted historic preservation legislation [FN241] and in 1978 the Supreme Court held that historic preservation "is an entirely permissible governmental goal." [FN242] Nevertheless, DPR suggests that the historic preservation portion of Section 9-301 may be unconstitutional because it authorizes not only regulation of historic buildings, but also regulation of undeveloped private land in historic districts. [FN243] "[T]he courts have consistently rejected the notion that nonhistoric structures are exempt from control [under historic preservation laws]." [FN244] And just as local governments may regulate nonhistoric buildings within historic districts, they may regulate undeveloped land within historic districts. For *687 example, in A-S-P Associates v. City of Raleigh, [FN245] the owner of a vacant lot within a historic district [FN246] asserted that "even if the [city's historic preservation] Ordinance is a valid exercise of the police power insofar as it applied to historic structures, it is invalid when applied to new construction on property such as [plaintiff's] vacant lot." [FN247] The landowner asserted that such zoning was unreasonable and thus was unconstitutional under the doctrine of "substantive due process," under which all arbitrary regulation of liberty or property constitutes a regulation without due process and thus violates the Fourteenth Amendment. [FN248]
The North Carolina Supreme Court rejected the landowner's substantive due process claim, for two reasons. First, "preservation of the historic aspects of a district requires more than simply the preservation of those buildings of historical and architectural significance within the district. . . . 'just as important is the preservation and protection of the setting or scene in which [structures of architectural and historical significance] are situated."' [FN249] Second, the zoning law did not totally prohibit development of new structures, but merely required the plaintiff "to construct them in a manner that will not result in a structure incongruous with the historic aspects of the Historic District." [FN250] DPR suggests that Section 9-301 may be unconstitutional because it applies to "undeveloped private land." [FN251] But in A-S-P Associates, the court held that a vacant lot within a historic district could be regulated. [FN252] In other words, "undeveloped private land" within historic districts may be regulated. Thus, DPR's argument was *688 rejected by the A-S-P Associates court and is unlikely to bar enforcement of Section 9-301.
3. Rezoning
Section 8-201(3) of the Guidebook contains a list of provisions that must be included in a zoning ordinance. DPR attacks this section not for any of its provisions, but for a sin of omission: that it "authorizes zoning of land uses and structures within the local jurisdiction without regard for current uses." [FN253] But the text of the SZEA shows that a zoning enabling act need not endorse existing land uses. Section 9 of that statute provides that "[w]herever the regulations made under the authority of this act . . . impose other higher standards than are required in any other statute or local ordinance or regulation, the provisions of the regulations made under authority of this act shall govern." [FN254] By allowing local governments to create "higher standards" for land use than authorized by other statutes, Section 9 of SZEA allows municipalities to use their zoning powers to overturn existing land use statutes. And if a municipality can reject existing statutes, it is by definition ignoring "current uses" of land. It logically follows that if Section 8-201(3) is unconstitutional, SZEA is also unconstitutional. This would be an absurd result given the courts' repeated approval of the many zoning laws patterned on SZEA. [FN255] In other words, SZEA shows no more regard for current uses than does the Guidebook. Thus, the continued survival of SZEA-inspired zoning laws suggests that Section 8-201(3) is constitutional.
4. Subdivision Approval *689 A subdivision is "any land, vacant or improved, which is divided or proposed to be divided into two or more lots, parcels, or tracts for the purpose of offer, sale, lease, or development, whether immediate or future." [FN256] Section 8-301(4) of the Guidebook provides that no person "shall subdivide any land until the . . . [map] designating the areas to be subdivided has been approved pursuant to this Section by the local government having jurisdiction over the land." [FN257] Subsection (b) of that model statute provides that "[a]ny purported subdivision of land or plat recordation of a minor subdivision, resubdivsion, or final plat that has not been so approved is void." [FN258]
DPR interprets Section 8-301(4) to mean that "[c]urrent subdivisions . . . that have not been approved by the local government pursuant to the Guidebook's recommendations are considered void." [FN259] Supreme Court precedent holds that government regulation is especially likely to constitute an unconstitutional "taking" if such regulation interferes with a landowner's "reasonable investment-backed expectations." [FN260] If a zoning enabling statute provides that a subdivision approved long ago is "void," obviously that statute interferes with subdividers' reasonable expectations and thus may well be an unconstitutional taking.
*690 Such an interpretation of Section 8-301(4), however, is probably incorrect. Subsection 8-301(4), as noted above, provides that no person "shall subdivide any land" without municipal approval. [FN261] The phrase "shall" is in the future tense. That is, it probably means that no one may subdivide land in the future without municipal approval and therefore does not mandate municipal re-approval of existing subdivisions. It logically follows that Section 8-301(4), if narrowly interpreted, is not constitutionally problematic. If Section 8-301(4) or a similarly worded state law is challenged in court, the court is likely to adopt such a narrow interpretation based on the principle that if "a statute is susceptible of two constructions, by one of which grave and doubtful constitutional questions arise and by the other of which such questions are avoided, [the court's] duty is to adopt the latter." [FN262]
5. Just Compensation and Transfers of Development Rights
A transfer of development rights (TDR) is a landowner's "yielding of some or all of the right to develop or use a parcel of land in exchange for a right to develop or use another parcel of land, or another portion of the same parcel of land, more intensively." [FN263] In the twenty-five states allowing TDR programs, [FN264] a local government may limit development of land it wishes to protect from development without paying cash compensation, as long as it compensates the landowner in-kind by allowing higher densities on other districts or parcels. [FN265] The Guidebook defines the land on which a TDR limits development as a "sending" district or parcel of land [FN266] and *691 defines the land that may be developed more intensively due to the TDR as the "receiving" district or parcel. [FN267] The receiving parcel need not be owned by the burdened landowner; instead, the landowner may sell her [FN268] TDR to a developer who wishes to exceed density limits on the receiving parcel. [FN269] Thus, "burdened landowners are paid market value for the property rights they lose and developers pay market value for the additional development rights they purchase." [FN270]
Section 9-401 of the Guidebook authorizes TDRs, providing that a "local government may adopt local land development regulations and amendments that include provisions for the transfer of development rights." [FN271] Section 9-401 defines a "transfer of development rights" as a procedure "whereby the owner of a parcel in the sending district may convey development rights to the owner of a parcel in the receiving district, whereby the development rights so conveyed are extinguished on the sending parcel and may be exercised on the receiving parcel." [FN272] The Guidebook seeks to protect landowners' finances by providing that "receiving districts" may not be "downzone[d] . . . to the degree that owners cannot make a reasonable use of their property." [FN273] Thus, under the Guidebook, TDRs may not be used to render private land completely valueless.
DPR argues that TDRs violate the Takings Clause by violating the Fifth Amendment's demand "that just compensation be paid in money." [FN274] In other words, the group *692 contends that TDRs are an attempt to compensate landowners for the taking of their land, but are not constitutionally acceptable because they are in-kind transfers rather than transfers of money. By contrast, the Guidebook's authors reason that by allowing landowners to make "a reasonable use of their property" [FN275] in the receiving district, a TDR-adopting municipality commits no taking requiring just compensation.
The Arizona Court of Appeals' decision in Corrigan v. City of Scottsdale [FN276] supports the former view. In Corrigan, a property owner challenged a zoning ordinance that prohibited new development within his land but awarded TDRs allowing development in adjacent land owned by the plaintiff. [FN277] The court found that the TDRs were a taking, reasoning: "[t]he city claims this action is a legitimate exercise of [zoning] police power and yet it attempts a form of compensation by way of transfer of density credits. If this were a valid exercise of police power there would be no need for any form of compensation." [FN278] The Corrigan court went on to hold that the TDRs did not constitute "just compensation" as required by the Arizona Constitution because that constitution "requires compensation for such a taking to be made by payment of money in an amount that has been judicially determined" [FN279] and TDRs thus violate that constitution by compensating landowners in land rather than in money. [FN280] Corrigan, standing alone, suggests that Section 9-401 may violate a constitutional requirement that "just compensation be paid in money." [FN281]
It is not clear, however, whether Corrigan is good law even in Arizona. The Arizona Supreme Court, in a decision addressing the proper measure of damages for the alleged taking, stated: "[w]e express no opinion as to the legality or *693 constitutionality of [the city's] scheme." [FN282] More importantly, Corrigan is of questionable relevance to cases interpreting the federal Constitution; the court's narrow interpretation of "just compensation" is based on the Arizona Constitution's requirement that "[n]o private property shall be taken or damaged for public or private use without just compensation having first been made, paid into court for the owner, secured by bond as may be fixed by the court, or paid into the State treasury . . . ." [FN283] The Arizona Constitution's references to compensation being "paid into court for the owner," "secured by bond," and "paid into the State treasury" imply that compensation may only be paid in cash. By contrast, the federal Constitution merely requires "just compensation" without adding details, thus arguably giving governments more flexibility in choosing the manner of compensation.
Finally, United States Supreme Court precedent [FN284] is inconsistent with Corrigan. In Penn Central Transportation Co. v. City of New York, [FN285] the Supreme Court rejected a Takings Clause claim by a landowner whose request to build a fifty-five-story office tower atop a historic train terminal was denied pursuant to New York City's historic landmark ordinance. [FN286] The landmark ordinance contained a TDR provision that allowed the owners of landmark sites to transfer development rights from a landmark parcel to other parcels owned by the same landowner. [FN287] The Court found that the historic landmark ordinance was not a taking, partially because of the TDR provision. The Court reasoned that even if the city outlawed all attempts to build above the terminal, [FN288] the TDR law precluded a finding that plaintiff had been denied all economically beneficial use of its air rights because the TDRs:
*694 made [plaintiff's rights] transferable to at least eight parcels in the vicinity of the Terminal, one or two of which have been found suitable for the construction of new office buildings. . . . While these rights may well not have constituted 'just compensation' if a 'taking' had occurred, the rights nevertheless undoubtedly mitigate whatever financial burdens the law has imposed on [plaintiffs] and, for that reason, are to be taken into account in considering the impact of regulation. [FN289]
In other words, Penn Central held that because the city's historic preservation law included a TDR, plaintiff's air rights were not worthless and thus no taking occurred. [FN290] If the presence of TDRs precludes an otherwise unconstitutional regulation from being a taking, it logically follows that TDRs are not themselves unconstitutional under the Takings Clause and that Corrigan is not relevant to federal constitutional claims. It could be that Penn Central is no longer relevant to most cases involving TDRs, based on Justice Scalia's concurrence in Suitum v. Tahoe Regional Planning Agency. [FN291] In Suitum, a landowner challenged a regional planning agency's decision that her lot was ineligible for development because it was in an environmentally sensitive area. [FN292] The regional planning agency sought to mitigate the harshness of its development restrictions by granting affected property owners TDRs; [FN293] rather than seeking to use those TDRs, plaintiff filed suit alleging a Takings Clause violation. The lower courts dismissed her claim on the ground that her claim was not ripe for judicial consideration, [FN294] reasoning that because plaintiff had not yet applied to use those TDRs, the value of her TDRs, and thus her economic losses caused by the TDRs, were not yet known. [FN295] The Supreme Court disagreed, reasoning that the *695 case was ripe for review because the parties agreed that the plaintiff did in fact have the right to sell her TDRs [FN296] and the valuation of plaintiff's TDR was an issue of fact, which could be resolved in federal court. [FN297]
Justice Scalia wrote a separate concurrence, joined by Justices O'Connor and Thomas. [FN298] In that concurrence, Justice Scalia wrote that the case was ripe for judicial action because a takings claim is ripe for review as soon as "the government had finally determined the permissible use of the land." [FN299] Justice Scalia added that in his view, the landowner's TDRs were irrelevant to the question of whether a taking occurred because even if the TDRs were equal in value to plaintiff's land, she had lost the right to use her own land. She thus suffered a taking even if she received the right to develop other land in exchange. [FN300] Instead, "the marketable TDR, a peculiar type of chit which enables a third party not to get cash from the government but to use his land in ways the government would otherwise not permit, relates not to taking but to compensation." [FN301]
More importantly, Justice Scalia added that he was not opposed to TDRs; rather, TDRs "may also form a proper part, or indeed the entirety, of the full compensation accorded a landowner when his property is taken." [FN302] By asserting that a TDR may constitute "just compensation," Justice Scalia bluntly repudiated the Corrigan court's suggestion that because a TDR is not in cash, it may not constitute "just compensation." [FN303] In sum, both the Penn Central Court and Justice Scalia's Suitum concurrence held that land use regulations that include TDRs do not automatically violate the Takings Clause. The Penn Central court so held because TDRs may prevent an *696 otherwise confiscatory regulation from constituting a "taking;" Justice Scalia because TDRs may constitute "just compensation" for such a taking. Either way, Section 9-401 and other statutes authorizing TDRs are constitutional on their face.
6. Crime and Punishment Under the Guidebook
Section 11-302(1) of the Guidebook provides that it is "a criminal offense to intentionally [or knowingly] violate the land development regulations of any local government." [FN304] This statute does not, however, specify the appropriate penalties for such criminal violations. Nevertheless, DPR suggests that Section 11-302 is unconstitutional because it "criminalizes and allows imprisonment for anyone who intentionally or knowingly violates any land development regulation." [FN305]
The Guidebook's criminal enforcement procedures are hardly unique; for example, the SZEA provides that a "violation of this act or of [any ordinance authorized thereby] is hereby declared to be a misdemeanor, and [a] local legislative body may provide for the punishment thereof by fine or imprisonment or both." [FN306] More importantly, courts usually uphold such statutes. For example, in Hadachek v. Sebastian, [FN307] the Supreme Court upheld a conviction of a petitioner "[who] was convicted of a misdemeanor for the violation of an ordinance of the city of Los Angeles which makes it unlawful for any person to establish or operate a brickyard or brick kiln, or any establishment, factory or place for the manufacture or burning of brick within described limits in the city." [FN308] The Court rejected claims that the ordinance violated the Equal Protection Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment [FN309] and constituted "the taking of property without compensation." [FN310]
*697 Because Hadachek fails to directly address the distinction between criminal and civil liability, that case is not directly on point. More recent state court decisions, however, explicitly allow criminal punishment for zoning violations. In City of North Royalton v. Vodicka, [FN311] police arrested the defendant for having an overly high fence, a misdemeanor offense under the city code. [FN312] The defendant asserted that "the classification of his [zoning code] violations . . . as fourth degree misdemeanors somehow violates his constitutional rights to equal protection and due process." [FN313] An Ohio court disagreed, finding no "constitutional infirmity in the application of these city zoning ordinances . . . [or] on the face of this legislative scheme." [FN314] In Calhoun v. Town Board Saugerties, [FN315] a New York court stated that where municipal law made violations of zoning ordinances a misdemeanor, those ordinances could be enforced as long as the state provided "minimal due process protections." [FN316] In sum, both common practice and case law support the conclusion that criminal punishments may be assessed for violation of zoning laws. It logically follows that the Guidebook's endorsement of such criminal penalties is constitutional.
7. Exactions
Rather than flatly granting or rejecting an application for a building permit, a government agency will sometimes grant permits on condition that "a developer provide certain improvements in a new development or, in some cases, pay a fee to cover the expense of the local government providing those improvements off-site." [FN317] These conditional permits are known as "exactions." [FN318] Local governments mandate exactions for two reasons. First, some improvements, such as streets, streetlights, and utilities, are "reasonably necessary for the public health, safety [and] welfare." [FN319] Second, "the *698 development itself is creating the demand for the improvements, and the public as a whole should not bear the cost of constructing improvements for new development." [FN320] Exactions are hardly new; SPEA [FN321] allows local governments to impose exactions for streets, open spaces, and utilities. [FN322]
Section 8-601(4) of the Guidebook provides that exactions for improvements "shall be in reasonable proportion to the demand for such improvements that can be reasonably attributed to developments subject to the ordinance." [FN323] Guidebook critics contend that this provision differs materially [FN324] from the rule set forth by the Supreme Court in Dolan v. City of Tigard. [FN325] In Dolan, a city allowed a landowner to double the size of her plumbing and electric supply store. [FN326] The municipality conditioned that approval upon flood control and traffic improvements, including the dedication of land for an easement/" greenway" [FN327] that recreational users could use to enter her land [FN328] and a pedestrian/bicycle pathway. [FN329] The plaintiff raised a Takings Clause claim, asserting that "the city has forced her to choose between the building permit and her right under the Fifth Amendment to just compensation for the public easements." [FN330]
The Court held that the city's exaction was constitutional only if "the degree of the exactions demanded by the city's permit conditions bears the required relationship to the projected impact of [the] proposed development." [FN331] Thus, the decisive legal issue was the nature of this "required relationship." The Court rejected the view that the city need only show "the 'reasonable relationship' test adopted by a majority of the state courts . . . because the term 'reasonable relationship' seems confusingly similar to the term 'rational basis' which describes the minimal level of scrutiny under the *699 Equal Protection Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment." [FN332] Instead, the appropriate test was "rough proportionality," meaning "the city must make some sort of individualized determination that the required dedication is related both in nature and extent to the impact of the proposed development." [FN333] Some Guidebook critics assert that Section 8-601 of the Guidebook, which authorizes exactions of various types, is inconsistent with the Dolan Court's "rough proportionality" test and instead endorses the "reasonable relationship" test rejected by the Supreme Court. [FN334]
But a careful reading of Section 8-601(4) suggests otherwise. Under this model statute, all improvements "required by an improvements and exactions ordinance shall be in reasonable proportion to the demand for such improvements that can be reasonably attributed to developments subject to the ordinance." [FN335] In other words, to satisfy the requirements of Section 8-601(4), a local government must do more than show that an exaction is somehow related to a development; instead, the burden of the exaction upon a developer must be "in reasonable proportion" to the impact of the development at issue. This language apparently tracks the Dolan Court's "rough proportionality" test.
*700 To the extent that Section 8-601(4) and similar state statutes are ambiguous on this point, such statutes are likely to be upheld based on the well-settled principle of statutory construction that if "a statute is susceptible of two constructions, by one of which grave and doubtful constitutional questions arise and by the other of which such questions are avoided, [the court's] duty is to adopt the latter." [FN336] Under this rule, the courts will uphold Section 8-601(4) because it is "susceptible" of being construed to affirm the Dolan Court's "rough proportionality" test. In other words, if Section 8-601(4) could reasonably be interpreted either to adopt the (incorrect) "reasonable relationship" test or the "rough proportionality" test endorsed by the Dolan Court, the courts will assume that that statute has the latter meaning in order to uphold its constitutionality. Because Section 8-601(4) requires that exactions "be in reasonable proportion to the demand for such improvements," that statute could reasonably be construed to adopt the "rough proportionality" test endorsed by the Dolan Court. Thus, Section 8-601(4) is constitutional.
8. Amortization of Nonconforming Uses
A "nonconforming use is a land use, or a structure, which was allowed under local land development regulations when established, but [which] would not be permitted under current development regulations." [FN337] States and local governments generally adopt one of two methods for dealing with nonconforming uses. The majority of states and local governments "grandfather" nonconforming uses. Thus, the locality allows a land use to continue as long as it was legal at the time it was commenced. [FN338] When the nonconforming use is terminated, the protection of grandfathering is lost and resumption of the nonconforming use is not allowed. [FN339] Some states, however, authorize "amortization" of nonconforming uses. Amortization requires "the termination of a nonconforming use after a period of time." [FN340] The Guidebook concedes that amortization is "a controversial land use *701 regulation technique, as owners of nonconforming uses can claim that the removal of a nonconforming use at the end of an amortization period, without compensation, is unconstitutional." [FN341]
Section 8-502(4) expressly authorizes amortization, providing that local governments may "state a period of time after which nonconforming land uses . . . must terminate" [FN342] or set forth criteria that designated local officials may, on a case-by-case basis, use to establish "a period of time after which a nonconforming land use . . . . must terminate." [FN343] Guidebook critics assert that Section 8-502(4) violates the Takings Clause by allowing local governments to terminate land uses without compensation. [FN344] Although the majority of courts uphold amortization in principle, [FN345] a few courts find amortization to *702 be unconstitutional under state versions of the Takings Clause. [FN346] Thus, amortization is unconstitutional under several state constitutions.
Although the Supreme Court has not yet explicitly addressed the status of amortization under the federal Constitution, the Court's case law is highly relevant. It is well-settled that under the federal Takings Clause, a land use regulation is generally [FN347] a compensable taking when a *703 landowner has suffered a total taking of her property. Such a total taking requires "[a] permanent 'obliteration of the value' of a fee simple estate." [FN348] This occurs "when no productive or economically beneficial use of [the] land is permitted." [FN349] But when a land use regulation diminishes the value of a landowner's property by less than 100 percent, [FN350] the federal courts apply the balancing test enunciated in Penn Central [FN351] and endorsed in more recent cases. [FN352] Under this "partial takings" test, federal courts weigh the "economic impact of the regulation on the claimant and, particularly, the extent to which the regulation has interfered with distinct investment-backed expectations . . . [as well as] the character of the governmental action." [FN353] The phrase "character of . . . government action" means that a regulation must be "reasonably necessary to the effectuation of a substantial public purpose." [FN354] It follows that unless amortization of nonconforming uses always deprives a landowner of one hundred percent of her property's fair market value, it is not per se unconstitutional under the federal Constitution and is subject to the case-by-case balancing test enunciated in Penn Central.
The few amortization cases that reveal any awareness of Penn Central hold that zoning ordinances amortizing nonconforming uses are "partial takings" requiring application of the Penn Central balancing test rather than unconstitutional "total takings." For example, in Board of Zoning Appeals, Bloomington, Indiana v. Leisz, [FN355] two landlords (a husband and wife) challenged a zoning ordinance that "limited the occupancy of dwellings in certain neighborhoods to a maximum *704 of three unrelated adults per unit." [FN356] The ordinance, enacted on June 8, 1985, provided that owners of nonconforming properties could continue to rent to more than three tenants per unit only if they registered with the city by October 1, 1985. [FN357] Thus, the ordinance combined (1) an amortization period of several months for landlords who failed to register and (2) grandfathering for landlords who chose to register. The plaintiffs failed to register and asserted that the ordinance was an unconstitutional taking because "any ordinance which bans an existing lawful use within a zoned area is unconstitutional as a taking of property." [FN358]
The Leisz court rejected the plaintiffs' argument that "amortization provisions are unconstitutional per se . . . [as] an issue of federal constitutional law" [FN359] for three reasons. First, the ordinance "involved no physical invasion of the [plaintiffs'] property." [FN360] Second, the ordinance "does not deny [the plaintiffs] all economically beneficial or productive use of their land . . . [but merely] denies them at most 25% to 40% of the rental income that they might otherwise receive." [FN361] Third, "state courts that have found amortization provisions unconstitutional have done so on the basis of their state constitution," rather than the federal Constitution. [FN362] The court went on to reject plaintiffs' claims under the Penn Central balancing test. [FN363] Thus, Leisz presents a classic example of a situation where a zoning law amortizing nonconforming uses did not deprive landowners of all economically beneficial use of their land. [FN364]
*705 Federal courts as well as state courts apply the Penn Central test to amortization-related cases. In Georgia Outdoor Advertising, Inc. v. City of Waynesville, [FN365] a city sought to "effectively prohibit all off-premise outdoor signs in the city" [FN366] by enacting an ordinance containing a four-year amortization period. [FN367] The Fourth Circuit rejected claims that amortization provisions either immunized zoning laws from constitutional scrutiny or automatically invalidated such laws. Instead, the court held that courts should apply the Penn Central balancing test [FN368] and that amortization provisions are "only 'one of the facts that the district court should consider"' [FN369] in deciding whether a zoning regulation constitutes an unconstitutional taking. [FN370]
*706 Similarly, in Naegele Outdoor Advertising, Inc. v. City of Durham, [FN371] a district court cited Penn Central in support of its holding that "the benefit conferred by the grant of an amortization period may be taken into account in considering the economic impact of the regulation." [FN372] Specifically, the court found an outdoor advertising company who challenged a city ordinance limiting off-premise signs "has not been deprived of all economically viable use of its property." [FN373] This was so partially because of the amortization period and partially because even after the amortization period ended, the plaintiff's revenue from signs in the relevant market would only be reduced by 29.75 percent. [FN374] The court went on to find that no taking occurred because the other elements of the Penn Central test also did not support the plaintiff's claim: the plaintiff's investment-backed expectations were either unreasonable or nonexistent [FN375] and the city's regulations were justified by a legitimate aesthetic purpose. [FN376] Thus, Naegele, like Georgia Outdoor, holds that amortization is not always an unconstitutional taking and that the Penn Central balancing test must be applied to amortization ordinances.
Although many opinions discuss amortization, only a few bother to consider Penn Central. Those cases suggest that zoning laws that (like Section 8-502(4)) provide for amortization of nonconforming uses are subject to the Penn Central balancing test and thus do not on their face breach the Takings Clause in every conceivable case. This does not mean, however, that such laws are always constitutional as applied. A municipal land use decision that renders a landowners' property economically useless or that otherwise goes "too far" [FN377] under the Penn Central test creates a compensable taking, amortization or no amortization. [FN378] So even though the *707 Guidebook's authorization of amortization is not per se unconstitutional, a municipality that chooses to amortize nonconforming uses may be at risk for Takings Clause lawsuits.

D. Tenth Amendment
The Tenth Amendment provides: "The powers not delegated to the United States by the Constitution, nor prohibited by it to the States, are reserved to the States respectively, or to the people." [FN379] The purpose of this amendment is to "allay lingering concerns about the extent of the national power" [FN380] by reserving to the states "a substantial portion of the Nation's primary sovereignty, together with the dignity and essential attributes inhering in that status." [FN381]
DPR suggests that the Guidebook creates "uniform national standards" [FN382] and thus violates the Tenth Amendment. But the Guidebook is not a model federal statute, but a set of model state statutes. [FN383] Although the Guidebook is federally funded, the Guidebook's opening pages state that it does not "reflect the views of HUD, the U.S. government, or any other project sponsor," [FN384] and the Secretary of HUD said that the Guidebook "does not have an imprimatur of the federal government, it does not have any sort of guidelines and there'll be no coercion for states or localities to adopt it." [FN385] Indeed, some Guidebook critics complain that the Guidebook increases, rather than decreases, state power. For example, one critic complains that the Guidebook forces localities to "abide by state-dictated land controls." [FN386] Because the purpose of the Tenth Amendment is to protect state power rather than local power, such concerns have no significance under the federal Constitution.
*708 The Guidebook may nevertheless constitute a federal intrusion into state prerogatives because it is funded by the federal government. Yet the SZEA was not only funded by the federal government, but drafted by the federal government. [FN387] So if the Guidebook is unconstitutional because of its federal support, the SZEA, and thus every state zoning enabling statute enacted pursuant to the SZEA, is unconstitutional. Given the courts' consistent endorsement of post-SZEA zoning, [FN388] this is an absurd result.

E. The Fourteenth Amendment
The Fourteenth Amendment provides, in relevant part, that no state shall "deny to any person within its jurisdiction the equal protection of the laws." [FN389] In the context of land use regulation, courts usually interpret the Equal Protection Clause to require "that classifications promote a legitimate government end in a rational way." [FN390] In zoning-related cases, this "restraint is more theoretical than real since [zoning] ordinances are reviewed under a highly deferential standard. Distinctions between commercial and residential use or types of commercial use, or between single-family and multi-family use are not likely to be invalidated." [FN391] Similarly, courts generally apply minimal scrutiny to local governments' aesthetic decisions and uphold findings by design review boards that certain structures are inharmonious with surrounding neighborhoods. [FN392]
*709 Nevertheless, DPR suggests that Section 9-301 of the Guidebook (which, as noted above, allows local governments to designate areas as "design review districts") [FN393] violates the Equal Protection Clause. DPR argues that the Guidebook allows local governments to "arbitrarily designate any area as a 'Design Review Districts' [sic] and subject property owners in just those areas to mandatory standards on the design and aesthetics of . . . their property." [FN394] According to DPR, the distinction between design review districts and other areas creates irrational "different treatment" [FN395] between property owners in design review areas and property owners in other areas.
If the Guidebook told local governments to randomly designate certain blocks as "design review blocks" this argument would be persuasive. But in fact, the Guidebook itself both includes criteria for designation of design review districts and orders local governments to enact such criteria. Section 9-301 of the Guidebook, which authorizes local governments to establish "design review districts," [FN396] limits local discretion to arbitrarily establish such districts by requiring that a design review district be a "geographically definable area possessing a significant concentration, linkage, or continuity of sites, buildings, structures, or objects united aesthetically by development or that, in the determination of the local legislative body, has the potential to be united aesthetically by development." [FN397] This provision is not the only limit upon local discretion. Section 9-301 requires that local governments themselves establish "criteria to be applied . . . in selecting areas to be designated by ordinance as design review districts." [FN398] Thus, a municipality that arbitrarily designates a *710 block or neighborhood as a "design review district" violates not only the Fourteenth Amendment, but the Guidebook as well.
Moreover, courts generally defer to aesthetic decisions by design review boards. For example, in Breneric Associates v. City of Del Mar, [FN399] a city design review board denied plaintiffs' building permit application on the ground that their proposed design "was inconsistent with the residence's architectural style and was inharmonious with the surrounding neighborhood." [FN400] The controversy revolved around plaintiffs' proposal to use glass on a house's roof deck and their proposed siting of an addition to the house. [FN401] A California court rejected plaintiff's equal protection claim, reasoning that the "denial of a permit bore a rational relationship to a permissible government objective because . . . the proposed development was rejected for transgressing aesthetic considerations, which are legitimate state objectives." [FN402] Further, "the facts cited in the resolution as the basis for [the city's] determination show that the 'wisdom [of the decision] is at least fairly debatable."' [FN403] Thus, Breneric Associates suggests that courts will uphold "fairly debatable" aesthetic decisions by local governments.
Sievert v. City of Mill Valley [FN404] also merits discussion. In that case, a city refused to allow plaintiffs to modify their home because the modification would "increase the apparent mass of the structure" [FN405] and thus violate a design review ordinance's requirement that a proposed structure not create "substantial disharmony with its locale and surroundings." [FN406] Plaintiffs raised an equal protection claim against the city, asserting that the city "arbitrarily denied plaintiffs' application while approving applications for other similarly situated applicants." [FN407] The court rejected that claim on two grounds. First, although the city approved building permits for nearby structures, plaintiffs failed to show that those structures were *711 "similarly situated" [FN408] in any way. Second, "building restrictions based upon visual impact are well within the legitimate objectives of local government" [FN409] and thus generally "rationally related to a legitimate government objective" [FN410] absent some evidence that the city acted for an improper purpose.
Breneric and Sievert are not directly on point because they involve municipal decisions that structures within areas governed by design review were inharmonious with their surroundings, while DPR questions the constitutionality of decisions that a given block or neighborhood should be within a design review district at all. Nevertheless, these cases do suggest that design-related decisions by local governments will generally be upheld under the Equal Protection Clause. Because Section 9-301 allows local governments to make design-related decisions, Section 9-301 and similarly worded state laws will also probably be upheld under the Equal Protection Clause.

F. Enabling Statutes and Unconstitutional Applications
"Historically, states are enablers. They authorize local governments to plan and regulate land use, but do not usually tell them how to do it." [FN411] The Guidebook's model statutes, if enacted by the states, will not change this pattern. Even if the Guidebook provisions referenced above are not unconstitutional on their face, they give local governments so much discretion that some applications of some municipal ordinances will create constitutional problems. For example, a municipal zoning decision, enacted pursuant to an otherwise constitutional state law or municipal ordinance, will violate the Takings Clause if the city totally eviscerates an individual landowner's property values. [FN412] Does the city's use of its zoning code to enact an unconstitutional taking mean that the state law authorizing municipal zoning is itself unconstitutional?
Again, SZEA is on point. SZEA is so broadly written that it could allow any number of unconstitutional decisions: it *712 allows local governments to regulate buildings in a wide variety of ways, [FN413] but does not explicitly limit the extent to which local governments may reduce a landowner's property values. But it does not follow that the dozens of state laws based on SZEA are unconstitutional. [FN414] Thus, the possible unconstitutionality of municipal zoning decisions does not render the Guidebook or similarly phrased state zoning enabling acts unconstitutional.


Conclusion
None of the Guidebook's most controversial provisions are unconstitutional on their face. Thus, state legislatures can safely enact the Guidebook into law if they please, especially if courts narrowly construe the Guidebook's more ambiguous and controversial provisions. This does not mean, however, that by doing so, states will immunize local zoning decisions from constitutional challenges. The Guidebook, like SZEA, authorizes local governments to enact zoning ordinances, but those ordinances will be subject to the same constitutional requirements that already limit government regulation of property rights.
Although the Guidebook may not raise significant constitutional concerns, its provisions implicate a variety of significant policy concerns. These issues include whether on-premise billboards create enough visual blight to justify local regulation, whether development moratoria are necessary to solve the problems occasionally created by new development, and whether amortization of nonconforming uses adequately protects landowners from the impact of zoning laws that outlaw preexisting land uses. As the Guidebook makes its way through state legislatures, legislators will have the responsibility of deciding whether the Guidebook correctly addresses these issues.
Because the Guidebook merely authorizes local governments to address these issues, rather than commanding them to do so, local governments, too, may be faced with difficult policy choices if states enact Guidebook-inspired enabling statutes--choices involving the balancing of private *713 property rights against the aesthetic and environmental concerns justifying many of the land use regulations discussed above.

Posted by lewyn at 3:02 PM EST
a very old St. Louis Post-Dispatch op-ed
February 18, 1991

HEY, ST. LOUIS, YOU'RE OK


By Michael E. Lewyn

In 1990, shortly after I moved to St. Louis, my former hometown of Atlanta was selected to host the 1996 Olympic Games. Because St. Louis is about the same size as Atlanta, local commentators suggested that St. Louis couldn't measure up to that winning Southern city. For instance, Ray Hartmann of The Riverfront Times wrote that Atlanta is a "world-class city" because its "citizens believe in each other," while "in St. Louis, unity doesn't even seem to extend beyond one's own limited sphere of activity." Hartmann claims that Atlanta is "unbeatable" because of its "biraciality," while St. Louis is doomed by its divisiveness. In fact, St. Louis has several advantages over Atlanta.

First, St. Louis is far safer than Atlanta. The table printed on this page shows 1989 crime rates per 100,000 people for St. Louis and Atlanta. If St. Louis had as much crime as Atlanta, 75 more city residents and 91 more suburbanites would have been murdered in 1989.

Not surprisingly, St. Louis residents are friendlier and less fearful than Atlantans. For instance, St. Louisans are more willing to live near poorer neighborhoods than Atlantans. In St. Louis, as in Atlanta, most whites do not want to live in or near heavily black neighborhoods. However, white St. Louisans are at least willing to live in the same city as blacks. Between 1960 and 1980, the white percentage of St. Louis' population dipped to 53 percent from 71 percent, a 18-point drop. By contrast, Atlanta's white population nosedived to 32 percent in 1980 from 62 percent of the city's population in 1960. As the city of Atlanta encompasses a much larger land area than St. Louis (131 square miles as opposed to 61), city population statistics understate the amount of "white flight" from Atlanta.

Indeed, some white Atlanta suburbanites will undergo considerable personal sacrifice to avoid contact with blacks. In 1980, Gwinnett County, one of metro Atlanta's fastest growing areas, voted to keep Atlanta's public transportation system out of the county. Why? According to USA Today, public transit opponents claimed that public transit would "bring crime many Gwinnett residents fled Atlanta to avoid. Some call that argument a subtle way of saying blacks aren't welcome in Gwinnett." In other words, many Atlanta suburbanites apparently believe that public transportation equals blacks, and blacks equal crime. Can anyone imagine Clayton (or even Creve Coeur) trying to keep out Bi-State buses?

Second, St. Louis is easier to get around in. Although Atlanta has a beautiful light-rail system, some areas within the city of Atlanta have virtually no access to public transit. For example, my parents live within the Atlanta city limits, just six or seven miles from downtown, but have no access to public transit. Here in St. Louis, I know people who live 10 to 20 miles from downtown and take the bus to work. Commuting by car is also somewhat easier in St. Louis. According to the 1980 census, the average St. Louis-area resident commutes 23 minutes to work; the average Atlanta-area commute is 26 minutes.

Third, St. Louis is much less of a two-class city than Atlanta. Although per capita income in Atlanta is higher ($10,341 as opposed to St. Louis' $8,799), Atlanta's poverty rate is also higher (27 percent as opposed to 21 percent). Thus, Atlanta has greater extremes of wealth and poverty than St. Louis. If St. Louis consisted solely of north city and West County, it would look like Atlanta.

Finally, St. Louis is much cheaper than Atlanta. I know a woman who just bought a house in South St. Louis for $45,000. To buy a house for that price in Atlanta, one would have to live in a drug infested slum or in a rural area 10 or 20 miles from the city.

As a past (and possibly future) Atlantan, I would not deny that Atlanta has some advantages over St. Louis: It is richer, more dynamic and has nicer weather. Nevertheless, St. Louis is better than St. Louisans think it is.

Posted by lewyn at 2:59 PM EST
an old Washington Post op-ed
November 5, 1995


OUTLOOK


CLOSE TO HOME


Myths About Metro

By reducing the number of cars on the road, public transportation reduces both air pollution and traffic congestion. Moreover, public transportation reduces welfare dependency by allowing the poor to get to work without having a car. Yet local politicians have raised Metrorail and Metrobus fares by 25 percent during the past five years while cutting service, because those politicians have been unwilling to invest in the Metro system.

Politicians base their hostility to Metro on the following five myths.

Myth 1: We don't have the money.

According to a recent study conducted by Price Waterhouse for the Metropolitan Washington Council of Governments, a one-cent-per-gallon increase in the gas tax (or reallocation of gas tax revenues from other services to Metro) would yield $24 million in revenue, enough to roll back Metro's most recent round of fare increases and service cuts.

Similarly, a 2 percent regional sales tax would yield $355 million in revenue, enough to make all Metro rides free. Furthermore, the same governors and state legislators who claim that there is no money for Metro improvements are willing to spend taxpayer funds on costly highway projects such as an inter-county connector and an outer Beltway.

Myth 2: Money spent on public transportation is wasted, because Metro ridership has been stagnating despite heavy federal support.

In fact, government has discouraged transit use in two ways. First, in the past several years Metro has raised Metrobus/Metrorail base fares twice while gas prices have remained stagnant. Not surprisingly, driving increased while transit use didn't. It logically follows that if government stopped punishing transit users, Metro ridership would increase.

Second, the federal government has indirectly encouraged driving by spending far more money on highways (which create development in auto-dependent suburbs) than on mass transit. In recent years, federal highway spending has exceeded mass transit spending by about a 5-1 margin.

Myth 3: Americans won't use mass transit, because they love the flexibility of cars.

Despite our government's highway mania, public transit is heavily used in many cities. For example, most New Yorkers (and about one-third of D.C. residents) use public transportation to get to work. By contrast, residents of cities with minimal mass transit systems usually drive to work. Thus, it appears that if mass transit is convenient, many workers will use it.

Indeed, this "flexibility" argument actually supports increased investment in Metro, because if a car gives a commuter flexibility, a car and a bus or Metro stop gives the commuter even more choices.

Myth 4: Metro (unlike highways) doesn't pay for itself, and drivers shouldn't have to subsidize bus riders.

Few government services "pay for themselves," making this argument frivolous. For example, in 1991 government at all levels spent $65 billion on highways but took in only $38 billion in fuel taxes. Thus, government subsidized about $27 billion in highway spending. Moreover, the taxpaying public pays for other driving-related government expenses such as the social costs of air pollution, the cost of police to enforce traffic and parking laws and to investigate vehicle accidents and auto theft, the cost of street maintenance and the cost of military spending to protect Persian Gulf oil supplies.

Myth 5: Because most new jobs are in the suburbs, Metro is obsolete.

This argument is a self-fulfilling prophecy. Mass transit makes traffic-choked downtowns and older suburbs (like Bethesda and Silver Spring) more convenient, while highways make newer, more distant suburbs easier to reach. Thus, Metro cuts will increase the economic gap between cities and suburbs and may eventually redistribute wealth from older suburbs like Bethesda to newer suburbs in outlying counties.

Continued investment in public transportation will increase labor force participation while controlling air pollution and traffic congestion. With a little money and a little leadership, we can save our investment in the Metro system rather than turning it into an overpriced, underused monument to governmental waste and incompetence.

-- Michael E. Lewyn

Posted by lewyn at 2:58 PM EST
old Buffalo News op-eds
October 24, 1998

EAST AURORA ESTABLISHED ITSELF AS A NEW URBANIST COMMUNITY DECADES BEFORE IT WAS COOL


MICHAEL E. LEWYN

Not long ago, "Nightline" ran a segment on New Urbanism -- a school of architecture that aims to replicate the sort of pedestrian- friendly "Main Street U.S.A." development that dominated American suburbs and small towns before World War II. This type of development is noticeable in Seahaven -- the mythical location of the film "The Truman Show" -- and Seaside, Fla., the real-life resort town on which Seahaven is based.

In New Urbanist communities, cars are part of the streetscape to a greater extent than in dense areas like midtown Manhattan, but they do not dominate the land to the extent that they do in most modern suburbs.

Thus, sidewalks are universal and residences and shops are in close proximity to a compact neighborhood center or "main street" so that children can walk to each other's houses or to shops.

In addition, shops are close to the street so that pedestrians can walk to them without spending 10 minutes walking through a parking lot; streets are narrow enough to be easily crossable by pedestrians; and on-street parking makes driving convenient while creating a buffer between pedestrians and traffic.

By contrast, in many American suburbs, residences and shops are rigidly separated from each other so that nobody can walk to anything, sidewalks are rare, parking lots are enormous and children are slaves to their parents' cars.

While watching the "Nightline" segment, I noticed that both New Urbanists and their critics acted as if New Urbanism was something new. But right here in Western New York, we have suburbs and neighborhoods that are quite similar to New Urbanist communities, built many decades before a few architects invented the term in the 1980s.

For example, East Aurora was New Urbanism before New Urbanism was cool. East Aurora has many of the New Urbanist elements: a compact neighborhood center (Main Street) a few blocks from most homes, shop entrances that front the street rather than parking lots, sidewalks everywhere and quaintness galore. East Aurora is not unique: Niagara- on-the-Lake is basically East Aurora with theaters and more shopping, and Chagrin Falls, Ohio, a suburb of Cleveland, is East Aurora with a waterfall and better shopping.

But East Aurora is not the only Western New York village with New Urbanist elements. Although Kenmore is less quaint and Disneyish than East Aurora, it, too, includes some elements of New Urbanism. Children roam the sidewalk-clad residential streets, all of which are within a few blocks of the main commercial street -- Delaware Avenue. On-street parking creates a buffer zone between pedestrians and traffic, and parking lots are less overwhelming than on the Buffalo side of Delaware Avenue. By contrast, just a few blocks away on Sheridan Drive or Niagara Falls Boulevard, the wide streets and huge parking lots have turned the roads into a jumble of cars, sky and not much else.

Obviously, the City of Buffalo also has neighborhoods that resemble New Urbanist communities, most notably the area around the Elmwood Strip -- Elmwood Avenue between Allentown and Delaware Park. The census tract where I live -- bounded by Main, Elmwood, Utica and Ferry -- is far more affluent than the average Buffalo neighborhood, yet a third of its households get by without cars, and can do their shopping on Elmwood rather than in suburbia. But the Elmwood Strip is a much more diverse, Bohemian area than Kenmore and East Aurora, with all the advantages and disadvantages that such diversity brings.

Areas like East Aurora illustrate not only our tradition of New Urbanism but also its success. One of the speakers on "Nightline" claimed that New Urbanism would create communities as congested and crime-ridden as cities. But East Aurora proves otherwise. The Town of Aurora, which encompasses East Aurora, had only one robbery in 1996, and otherwise compares favorably with most suburbs. Although Kenmore is a bit less perfect due to its relative proximity to poorer city neighborhoods, its crime rates are lower than those of the average suburb of Atlanta or Washington, D.C.

Similarly, an ABC reporter asked one architect whether the typical strip-mall dominated suburban landscape wasn't really "what people want." But in fact, communities like East Aurora appear to be as desirable as other affluent suburbs. Although East Aurora and, to a greater extent, Kenmore have had stagnant population in recent years, the same is true of more typically suburban Erie County communities like Hamburg and West Seneca.

And throughout the country, other older communities with New Urbanist features like Chagrin Falls are still prestigious areas. "What people want" is determined not by allegiance to some abstract school of urban design, but by the absence of poverty and the ills that come with it, such as crime and poor schools. And if people can find those advantages in New Urbanism-type communities, they will happily move to such communities.

Sunday, October 5, 1997

WHAT BUFFALO CAN LEARN FROM CLEVELAND

MICHAEL E. LEWYN -

When I moved from Cleveland to Buffalo a couple of months ago, I was surprised by Cleveland's favorable image here. Although I had always thought of Cleveland as an aging industrial city much like Buffalo, I learned that many Western New Yorkers think of it as a role model.

The fascination seems to come about because Cleveland has a couple of downtown museums and a couple of thousand middle-class downtown residents -- not as many as in larger cities, but more than in Buffalo (at least if one counts the areas within walking distance of most office buildings, as opposed to neighborhoods two or three miles away).

Unfortunately, some people have drawn the wrong lessons from Cleveland's improvements. I therefore submit for Buffalonians' consideration a few lessons I learned from living in downtown Cleveland:

Lesson 1: No museums, no zoos Some Western New Yorkers think that Buffalo can acquire a "24-hour downtown" by building a museum at the site of the downtown auditorium, or by moving the zoo to the waterfront. This view is incorrect because museums and zoos, like office buildings, are generally open only during 9 to 5 daylight hours. It follows that even if museums and zoos increase area tourism, they will do nothing to contribute to downtown's nighttime vitality.

Cleveland's Rock Hall of Fame and Science Center are on the northeastern tip of downtown -- one of downtown's duller areas after the museums' closing hours. Most of Cleveland's new residential development has been in the western half of downtown, far from the Rock Hall.

Lesson 2: No new sports Occasionally it's argued that bringing the Bills downtown might revitalize downtown Buffalo. This claim is meritless. Sports facilities are only open for a few days a year (81 for baseball, fewer for other sports) -- not enough to encourage residential construction around those facilities.

Cleveland has always had its sports stadiums downtown yet has only recently had a surge in downtown residential construction -- most of which is at the other end of downtown from the stadiums -- like the Rock Hall, they're at the east end.

Lesson 3: Housing variety Both downtown Cleveland housing and Buffalo Theater District housing are dominated by loft apartments, because existing buildings can easily be renovated into lofts. Yet I lived in downtown Cleveland but not in downtown Buffalo. Why? Because Cleveland had other options. I wanted to live in the sort of high-rise, high-security building that dominates midtown Manhattan and central Philadelphia (or that some of our office buildings could become). I found the right building in downtown Cleveland -- but in Buffalo, it was a few miles farther north.

The downtown should offer a variety of housing options.

Lesson 4: Build near work Buffalo should be encouraging development in the blocks closest to downtown office buildings. The city already has some housing within a mile or so of where I work -- townhouses on the waterfront and lofts in the Theater District. But there is almost no housing within a few blocks of most downtown office buildings. That means walking to work in downtown Buffalo would be very inconvenient -- especially when the winter winds begin to explode.

By contrast, in Cleveland I found an apartment a block and a half from work -- a far more attractive option. If Buffalo had housing within true walking distance of work, downtown would be far more appealing.

Lesson 5: Put cops on foot I lived at the east end of downtown Cleveland, in a block which (although otherwise quite dull and deserted) was unusually well policed. By contrast, on Buffalo's Main Street I have seen a few panhandlers but no police officers -- not a reassuring sign.

Lesson 6: Not just downtown Saving downtown won't, by itself, save a city. Despite downtown Cleveland's revitalization, the rest of Cleveland is arguably in worse shape than Buffalo -- probably because Cleveland has five major highways within city limits, making suburban living unusually convenient.

Fewer than 10 of the attorneys in my Cleveland firm lived in the City of Cleveland. By contrast, I would guess that as many as a third of the attorneys in my Buffalo firm live in the City of Buffalo. My perusal of high school, college and alumni directories suggests that both firms are typical of the professional classes of Buffalo and Cleveland.

Buffalo has some attractive neighborhoods, but its downtown is still pretty dull after 5 p.m. If Western New Yorkers want to equal or improve upon Cleveland's record, they need to learn from Cleveland's successes and from its failures.

Posted by lewyn at 2:57 PM EST
My amazon.com book reviews (for those of you who wonder what I've been reading)
http://www.amazon.com/gp/cdp/member-reviews/ARD5I31J12UU8/ref=cm_aya_rev_all/002-9220984-8362452

Posted by lewyn at 2:52 PM EST
Planetizen op-eds (reprinted by permission of planetizen.com)
Zoning Without Zoning
By Michael Lewyn
Nov 24, 2003

Houston, Texas is the only large American city with no formal zoning code -- yet Houston has all the sprawl and associated ills of other Sunbelt cities. Houston is less dense than most big cities, and Houstonians drive more than in most big cities. Does it then follow that sprawl is the result of consumer choice rather than of government meddling?

Not necessarily -- because what other cities achieve through zoning, Houston achieves through several land use regulations.

Like other cities' zoning codes, Houston's municipal code creates auto dependency by artificially spreading out the population. Until 1999, the city required all single-family houses to gobble up 5,000 square feet of land. Although this limit is less rigid than minimum lot sizes in most suburbs, the city's statute nevertheless insures that many residents will be unable to live within walking distance of a bus stop, which in turn means that those residents will be completely dependent on their cars. In 1999, the City Council partially deregulated density in neighborhoods closer to downtown. But since 98% of the city's housing was built before 1999, this change in the law is of little importance.

Houston's parking regulations also create automobile dependency by encouraging driving and discouraging walking. Under Houston's city code, virtually every structure in Houston must supply plenty of parking. For example, apartment buildings must have even more parking spaces than residents; landlords must supply 1.25 parking spaces for each efficiency apartment and 1.33 parking spaces for every bedroom. Offices, supermarkets, and other businesses are subject to similar restrictions. Such parking regulations discourage walking by forcing pedestrians to navigate through massive parking lots (and to dodge the vehicles driving them) to reach shops or jobs. And where walking is uncomfortable, most people will drive. In addition, minimum parking requirements, by taking land for parking that could have been used for housing or businesses, also reduce density, thus making the city less compact and more auto-dependent.

Houston's street design rules also make life more difficult for pedestrians. The city code requires most major streets to have a 100 foot right-of-way and residential streets must have a 50-60 foot right-of-way. Thus, Houston's streets can be up to 100 feet wide. By contrast, most modern streets are 32-36 feet wide, and pre-World War II streets are usually 28-30 feet wide. Such wide streets are difficult for pedestrians to cross because a wider roadway takes longer to cross, thus increasing the amount of time a pedestrian is exposed to traffic. And because wider roadways are designed for faster speeds, such roads are more dangerous for pedestrians.

Houston's block designs are equally unhelpful to pedestrians. The city code mandates that intersections on major streets be 600 feet apart. By contrast, a recent Environmental Protection Agency report recommends that for "a high degree of walkability, block lengths of 300 feet...are desirable." Houston's long, intersection-free blocks deter walking because a block with few intersections gives pedestrians few places to cross the street and few means of reaching a destination on a side street.

Finally, government at all levels has accelerated sprawl by building more roads to the urban fringe in Houston than in other cities. For example, Chicago has more than twice as many residents as Houston, yet has only 10% more freeway miles. Big Brother's reckless road building has encouraged development to shift to newer areas with minimal bus service -- but apparently has done little to reduce traffic congestion. According to the Texas Transportation Institute, Houstonians lost 36 hours per person in 1999 to traffic congestion, more than all but three other American cities (Los Angeles, San Francisco and Dallas).

In sum, Houston's land use regulations have historically been nearly as meddlesome, as pro-sprawl, and as anti-pedestrian as zoning in other American cities -- and have yielded similar results. The good news is that Houston is beginning to change its ways: minimum lot size requirements were loosened in 1999, and widened roads are actually beginning to become controversial. But it may take decades of real deregulation to undo the damage caused in the late 20th century.

Campaign of Sabotage
By Michael Lewyn
Mar 31, 2003

Transit users are second-class citizens in most American cities and suburbs. For example, the Boston metropolitan area has a subway system serving its urban core and a commuter train system serving its suburbs - yet even in metropolitan Boston, just 32% of entry-level employers are within one-quarter mile of a transit stop.1 And the situation is even worse in smaller cities, many of which have no bus service after rush hour.2

Why do American communities have so little transit service? Pundits and politicians justify the status quo on the grounds that, in the words of Tom DeLay, public transit "has failed in this country . . . despite a taxpayers' investment of over $100 billion."3 The story told by transit critics is a simple one: government spends money on public transit, yet most Americans don't use it. Thus, public transit is a waste of money.

But this story overlooks an important fact: far from encouraging Americans to use buses and trains, government at all levels has inadvertently sabotaged public transit by:

*Funding the competition. Until the 1960s, the federal government spent billions of dollars on highway building,4 but did not support trains and streetcars (which were generally run by private companies until competition from government highways made them into money-losers).5 And today, the federal governments spends more than four times as much money on highways as on transit (over $30 billion per year for highways, about $7 billion for transit).6 New and widened roads often go to suburbs without significant transit service, and thereby open up those areas for development.7 Thus, highway spending shifts people and jobs to areas without public transit, thus gutting transit ridership.


*Unfunded mandates. The federal government has effectively reduced transit service by loading down transit agencies with unfunded mandates. For example, the Americans with Disabilities Act (which requires transit systems to provide accessible service to the disabled) costs transit providers $1.4 billion per year,8 and Section 13-c of the Federal Transit Act (which limits transit systems' ability to reduce labor costs by laying off employees)9 costs transit providers $2-3 billion per year.10 Thus, about half of federal transit subsidies are canceled out by the costs of federal regulation.


*Paying Americans to move to auto-dependent suburbs. Since 1934, the Federal Housing Administration (FHA) has insured home mortgages. For the first few decades of its existence, FHA insured mortgages only in "low-risk areas" (usually defined as newer, whiter areas, i.e., suburbs), thus making suburban homes cheaper than urban homes.11 Because suburbs usually have less transit service than cities, FHA policies reduced transit ridership.


*Packing poverty into cities. New Deal-era public housing legislation encouraged cities to build public housing for the poor, but gave suburbs veto power over public housing,12 and in fact discouraged suburbs from building public housing by mandating that one unit of substandard housing be eliminated for each unit of public housing built13 (thus ensuring that suburbs with little substandard housing could not build public housing). By packing public housing for the poor into cities, federal law packed poor people into cities. Because middle-class people tend to avoid the poor and problems associated with poverty (such as crime), federal public housing law encouraged middle-class flight to suburbia, which in turn reduced transit ridership as families moved from transit-packed cities to auto-dominated suburbs.


*Using school systems to drive commuters into suburbia. Most states mandate that students be assigned to schools based on their home address ? which means urban children go to urban schools and suburban children go to suburban schools.14 Because cities tend to have more poverty than suburbs, city schools tend to have more children who are from low-income backgrounds (and thus harder to educate) than suburban schools. Thus, state laws effectively mandate that cities have worse schools than suburbs, thus encouraging middle-class flight from cities, thus reducing transit ridership.


*Using zoning laws to make suburbs as auto-oriented as possible. Many American municipalities have enacted minimum lot size laws to reduce population density; for example, the average Atlanta-area acre contains no more than a home or two.15 Public transit is less feasible in low-density areas: as residences are spread farther apart, fewer commuters can walk convenient distances to bus and train stops. Thus, zoning in its current form reduces transit ridership.

In sum, a wide variety of government policies have had the effect of sabotaging, rather than promoting, public transit. Nevertheless, transit ridership has actually been growing since 1995 - and if government ever reduces its anti-transit activism, this trend might continue.


Footnotes

1. Conservation Law Foundation, City Routes, City Rights 20 (1998). See also Michael Lewyn, Thou Shalt Put No Stumbling Blocks Before The Blind, 52 Hastings Law Journal 1037, 1041-43 (2001) (citing similar statistics for other cities and metropolitan areas).

2. Id. at 1042-43. See also David G. Oedel, The Legacy of Jim Crow in Macon, Georgia, in Just Transportation 97 (Robert D. Bullard and Glenn S. Johnson, eds. 1997).

3. 137 Cong. Record H8199-02 (1991), available at 1991 WL 213667.

4. Lewyn, supra at 1045-47 (discussing history of federal highway spending in more detail).

5. Paul Weyrich & William S. Lind, Conservatives and Mass Transit: Is It Time For A New Look? 10 (1996).

6. See Budget Plans to Shape TEA-21 Renewal, Transfer, March 14, 2003, available online at http://www.transact.org/transfer/trans03/03_14.asp#3 (noting current budget baseline of $31.6 billion for highways, $7.2
billion for transit).

7. See Lewyn, supra at 1048-51 (making argument in more detail, and in particular citing National Association of Home Builders survey showing that 55% of home buyer would move to a newer area if highway access improved); Sierra Club v. US DOT, 962 F. Supp. 1037, 1043 (N.D. Ill. 1997) ("Highways create demand for travel and [suburban] expansion by their very existence").

8. Testimony of the American Public Transportation Association, Subcommittee on Surface Transportation of the House Committee on Transportation and Infrastructure, Sept. 26, 1996, 1996 WL 10831544. See also Brian Doherty, Disabilities Act: Source of Unreasonable Accommodations, San Diego Union-Tribune, July 16, 1995 at G1 (ADA's paratransit provisions alone cost transit agencies $1.1 billion per year). Because these figures are several years old, they may underestimate the ADA's costs.

9. Editorial, Untied, Houston Chronicle, June 29, 1995 at 36, available at 1995 WL 5912413 (statute mandates that transit agencies pay six years' wages and benefits to employees affected by layoffs).

10. John-Walters, Bus-Jacking the Revolution, Policy Review, Jan/Feb. 1996 at 8.

11. Kenneth Jackson, Crabgrass Frontier 207 (1985).

12. Id. at 224.

13. Michael H. Schill & Susan Wachter, The Spatial Bias of Federal Housing Law and Policy, 143 U. Pennsylvania Law Review 1285, 1293 (1995).

14. Lewyn, supra at 1058.

15. Arthur C. Nelson, Exclusionary Practices and Urban Sprawl in Metropolitan Atlanta, 17 Ga. St. U. L. Rev. 1087 (2001) (discussing exclusionary zoning in Atlanta, and noting that as a result average lot size in metro Atlanta over 3/4 of acre).

Sprawl = Injustice
The sprawling suburbanization of America has implications for both planning and social justice -- it penalizes the millions of Americans who are too poor to drive. Mr. Lewyn calls for a "no roads without transit" policy.
By Michael Lewyn
Apr 09, 2001

When Americans argue about suburban sprawl (that is, the movement of people and jobs from cities to thinly populated auto-dependent suburbs), they typically argue about the convenience of the middle class. Environmentalists argue that the growth of suburbia lengthens the commutes of the middle class, and turns suburbs into congested clones of the cities that suburbanites fled; developers and their political allies call suburbia the "American Dream" and swear that sprawl means less congestion rather than more.

But there are larger issues at stake. For over 3000 years, the Judeo-Christian tradition has condemned those who sought to make the poor poorer. For example, the Bible dictates to ancient Israel's legal authorities: "Ye shall do no unrighteousness in judgment; thou shalt not respect the person of the poor, nor favor the person of the mighty" (Leviticus 19:15). These words of wisdom do not mandate abolition of poverty -- but they do warn that the coercive arm of the state may not be used to impoverish the already poor in order to make life more convenient for the affluent majority.

But sprawl-promoting government policies do exactly that. For the past century, government has built highways to suburban areas with minimal or nonexistent public transit, thereby making it convenient for businesses and civic facilities to abandon transit-friendly cities and move to car-dependent suburbs. By making car ownership a necessity for work and play, sprawl penalizes the millions of Americans who are too poor to drive and the 24 million disabled Americans who are physically incapable of driving, freezing them out of the labor market and out of civic life.

For example, a few years ago Georgia's government built a road called Georgia 400, which made a suburb called Dunwoody far more convenient to businesses and homeowners. Atlanta's Jewish Community Center, taking its cues from Big Brother, abandoned midtown Atlanta and moved to a Dunwoody road where bus service ends two hours before the center closes and evaporates on weekends. So unless the JCC decides to provide shuttle service on its own, the 39% of Atlanta's African-American households that own no vehicle can't reach jobs at the JCC, and the children and elderly who the center is meant to serve can't reach the JCC without begging the powers that be for rides. Other Atlanta jobs have moved to Gwinnett County, a suburb of 500,000 people which has no public transportation whatsoever. Nevertheless, the Atlanta Regional Commission, the region's transportation planning agency, plans to widen thirteen roads and build or extend three more in Gwinnett County, thus ensuring that even more people and jobs will move there. (To be fair, the ARC does claim that it will institute a bus system in Gwinnett--but it may take decades for bus service to catch up with the area's highways).

In Rust Belt metro areas like Buffalo and Cleveland, rich and poor live in separate municipalities. In such areas, the poor are even worse off than in Sun Belt cities that have annexed suburban areas. This is so because in growing Sun Belt cities like Charlotte and Albuquerque, rich and poor share one tax base and one set of city services. All citizens therefore share minimally decent city services, and city taxes are low because the tax base includes rich and poor alike. By contrast, in most Rust Belt cities, the rich get to live in suburbs with superb tax bases and fine services, while the poor get penned up in cities with weak tax bases that force municipal politicians to choose between high taxes and poor services. In other words, sprawl (combined with state laws restricting cities' ability to annex their suburbs) creates not just unequal justice for rich and poor, but entirely separate governments for rich and poor.

Just as the Judeo-Christian tradition condemns American suburban sprawl, that tradition also suggests possible solutions, solutions based on equity rather than competing values such as shaving a few minutes off suburbanites' commutes.

A public policy based on justice would not eliminate suburban development or force people to move back into older cities, but would require that some of the so-called benefits of government-generated sprawl trickle down to the powerless.

For example, state and federal governments could implement a "no roads without transit" policy, requiring that any new or widened roads be accompanied by bus service that allows the poor, the disabled, the young and the old to reach business development generated by those roads and their interchanges. A more ambitious proposal would be to compensate transit-dependent Americans for past roadbuilding sprees, by require some minimal level of bus service to every significant employer. According to one staffer at the American Public Transportation Association (who opposed the proposal), hourly bus service to every employer with 15 or more employees would cost $1 billion (only 1% of government transportation spending). Such proposals are a logical extension of current law. Today, the Americans with Disabilities Act requires that the disabled be given bus service comparable to that given to the citizenry as a whole, regardless of cost. If we can disregard efficiency considerations to make disabled bus riders equal to other bus riders, we can do the same to make them equal to the citizenry as a whole.

We could also eliminate the system of suburban governments that creates one government for the rich and another for the poor. Specifically, states could mandate city-county mergers so that rich and poor would share the same government services, or at least mandate some form of regional tax sharing to limit fiscal disparities between richer and poorer cities.

It could be argued that since rich people pay more taxes, they are entitled to better government. Leaving aside the moral problems with this argument, it is based upon an incorrect factual assumption: our tax system as a whole is not particularly progressive, because the progressive federal income tax is offset by state sales taxes and Social Security taxes (both of which make the poor pay more than the rich) and by to some extent by local property taxes (which often hits people living in poor cities the hardest, because those towns have smaller tax bases and thus higher taxes or worse services). It could be also argued that the division of metropolitan areas into dozens of governments reduces taxes by creating competition between cities. But the high taxes of Buffalo and its suburbs belie this argument.

Whenever any scheme to improve the lot of the disadvantaged is proposed, some will cry "redistribution." But curing the impacts of government-financed sprawl does not require that the market be tampered with or that poverty be abolished, but only that government stop redistributing income away from the poor--that is, that government stop segregating the poor into poor cities and stop using transportation policy to steer jobs away from the poor.






Posted by lewyn at 2:50 PM EST
old journal of Israel trip
Below is a journal I wrote after visiting Jerusalem in 2002. If you don't like what I wrote or thought then, just remember that it was some time ago, and I'm sure I'd do a better job now!

In the summer of 2002, I went to Jerusalem as part of a group tour, the Rally in Israel (www.rallyinisrael.org). The idea was that a few Jewish organizations would subsidize a mass trip to Israel, and thousands of young Americans would come to a big rally that would get worldwide publicity, and pump some money into the local economy while they were doing it. They didn't raise as much money as anticipated so Rally was not as big as hoped - maybe next year will be better.

Sunday August 11: Arrived Sunday morning at JFK. Spent an hour at security, mainly because they xray checked baggage (worthwhile seeming but apparently Americans too cheap to do it) and asked weird questions ("why are you in Israel?"). Then got in another line to get to gate - but unlike in America no random repetitive searches (unlike AirTran flight back in LaGuardia). Everyone gets their coat searched, but they don't do it twice, since El Al has odd notion that purpose of security is to detect bombs rather than prove political correctness. (In NYC AirTran flight, American govt. pinheads searched shoes once at beginning of C course and then searched every third passenger or so at gate).

Flight took off 12ish--biggest plane I have ever seen. First class was upstairs, rest of us downstairs. I was in row 52 and there were 8 or 10 rows back of me, so there must have been at least 600 passengers. I sat next to Assemblies of God fellow from Lufkin, Tx. We discussed God, theology, other light stuff - pretty civil though, no attempt to convert me. Apparently this man had had some sort of mystical born again experience. He thinks God has sent Bush to save day from terrorists; I am somewhat less optimistic.

Despite size of flight, El Al flight definitely less unpleasant than US flights. People were wandering around halls, going to middle aisles to get food themselves from attendants. Flight to Israel more sociable than flight from - my suspicion was that flight to had lots of people from same yeshiva or something, since I saw kids in back hats. Whole thing generally clubby. Didn't hurt that wine and beer was free.

One interesting thing: REAL forks and knives at meals. In fact I cut myself; my suspicion is that there were enough well-armed air marshals that no one cared about kitchen knives.

Monday August 12- Got into airport around 5:30 or 6, but bus didn't leave for airport till around 7 - partially because of security (we had to stand in line to flash passport, answer silly-seeming questions). Bus from Tel Aviv to Jerusalem ran mostly through agricultural territory - it seemed like there were a lot of different crops, not nearly as monotonous as most American farmland. Guide says sunflower seeds, cotton some of crops. As I got further from airport, land grew more lush, more forests closer to Jerusalem (more evergreens than in most of USA). However, I later learned that there was not enough trees to support wood houses and things like that; all houses in Jerusalem are of stone.

Guide said that people routinely packed firearms; certainly when I was in Jerusalem I saw plenty of security guards packing heat, and in fact there was one on our tour bus.

When we enter Jerusalem (hereinafter "J" to save me typing time) I understood why the term "aliyah" means "going up" - J. on higher elevation then nearby areas, so if you are going to J. you are going up physically as well as (perhaps) spiritually. Outskirts of J seemed thinly populated; I guess J is a hyperelastic city (i.e. one that annexes suburbs, like Houston or Oklahoma City, rather than one trapped inside its 1950s boundaries, like Buffalo). Traffic jam very serious, because of (1) absence of rail system and (2) fear of buses due to bus bombings. Also, people who used to take country roads scared off by drive by shootings, so they were all packed onto relatively secure main highway. Cars VERY small by USA standards, no SUVs etc.

Got to hotel (Dan Panorama Hotel, formerly Mariah, in modern urban area near a bunch of other hotels) around 8, spent an hour bathing, changing clothes etc. Spent morning trying to get connection for razor (success after 3 tries). Hotel nice enough, but a little less opulent than American hotels, in ways you don't notice until you've stayed there a day or two (e.g. no soda machines, fewer newspapers in gift shops, trivial stuff). Area around hotel has lots of bus service, walkable narrow streets, but not very mixed use (in terms of restaurants nearby other than one or two places that looked expense account oriented)

As tour bus drove through city I got some initial impressions:

*Climate VERY dry; we were told to drink LOTS of water to avoid dehydration, more of an issue than in humid environment like Atlanta I guess. First time I had ever been in dry heat; not much fun because of constant need to drink.

*architecture incredibly monotonous. EVERYTHING made of stone, either brown or light gray. Tour guide says British mandated this, my cousin Dov (70 something prof at Hebrew University) blames absence of wood nearby. J has around 500-750,000 people, same as DC or Baltimore.
Contrast with Buffalo (where I spent previous week) was especially stark; parts of Buffalo full of Victorians with all different colors, a vivid purple or two, a bright blue/purple here and there, though of course many that weren't as exciting.

*City has beautiful vistas; because it is so hilly there are plenty of places with magnificent views. This allowed me to notice that there was a ton of undeveloped land close in, unlike in American cities. Tour guide says that hilly land is more expensive to build on, more issues re water sewer etc. - seemed to think problem was affluence (not enough of it) rather than political situation.

*Street signs all in Arabic and English as well as Hebrew.

*City streets very narrow, seemed very walkable (as in fact they are) though lots of parking on sidewalk.

*A fair amount of street trees, but since buildings taller than trees no feeling of lushness--I guess newer areas were desert until recent decades, so maybe trees not that old.

*Lions (plastic I think) everywhere. Lots of American cities have animal statutes spread through city for fun (Buffalo with bisons, kind of like baseballs in Atlanta). Eventually they will be auctioned off much like Buffalo statutes.

At 11, bus went to Gilo, technically a West Bank settlement, but so close to J. really an inner ring suburb. Shows how close everything is to each other, city neighborhoods very close to some so-called settlements, both very close to Arab areas - one reason peace difficult perhaps, not a lot of space to separate enemies or create natural boundaries. Physical look at Gilo like rest of J. - everything light brown, everything multifamily (I don't think I ever saw a detached single family house).

After Gilo got dropped off at Ben Yehuda Street (intown pedestrian mall/fastfood area). Had fast food lunch (boring chicken shawarma), bought some souveniers, was bothered by sea of panhandlers eventually. Ben Yehuda street lively, lots of apartments above shops,kind of a New Urbanist dream. All types of people--university kids, a few black hatted very Orthodox types (not just confined to a few neighborhoods as in USA) . Took long nap.

Spent ALL Monday from 5:30 at Western Wall of Temple (built around 70 years before end of 2nd Temple by Herod). Did long tour of newly excavated tunnel, which is part of western wall that had been sealed up until 1967 war (was under Muslim Quarter of Old City, that is the part of Jerusalem that was entire city until 19th century or so). Most amazing thing is this: in theory, holiest area of Wall should be area closest to Holy of Holies (part of Temple where even High Priest could rarely go)--and that part was in the tunnels so we got to go there.

As some of you know, visitors to the Wall like to write out little prayers and put them in cracks of Wall. Friends & family had given me prayers to put in, or asked me to write some paraphrasing their wishes, so I did. I put them in part of tunnels closest to Holy of Holies.

Then we prayed at Wall. Prayer was not in tunnels, but at part of Wall that had been open to public for most of past 2000 years or so. There wasn't one big group, but instead several little minyans that sprouted up informally. (A minyan, 10 or more people, is required for most Jewish prayers). (Men and women separated, as in Orthodox synagogues). Prayer books all in Hebrew of course. We could see Dome of Rock (part of Muslim mosque on Dome of Rock, fairly holy Muslim site) from Wall--on site of Temple itself, and site of Ariel Sharon visit that first provoked Arab riots in fall 2000.

After brief dinner in Jewish Quarter of Old City (which I saw only tiny bit of that day, saw more of on Tuesday) (dinner was falafel - most interesting part is toppings very different from in USA. In USA falafel usually goes with tehini sauce - in Israel with french fries, pickles, hummus, and weird spices).

After dinner we went to first part of Rally, welcoming ceremonies. Chief rabbi of Israel spoke on "love thy neighbor as thyself." He said that this Biblical passage means loving your neighbor because he is LIKE yourself, i.e. person like you, etc. And in particular, Jews part of same corporate body of Judaism so we should love each other especially. Michael Melchior (deputy foreign minister) also spoke about why we were here (to comfort Israelis, to let them know world Jewry cares, etc.)

After Melchior spoke we prayed again at Wall. (Explanation for non - Jews: during weekday, very devoted Jews pray three times - morning, late afternoon, evening. This was the evening service).

The most elevating part of the whole trip was here, on Monday night. I said the prayer (in Hebrew) "Holy, Holy Holy is the Lord of Hosts" - and remembered that I was doing this just a few yards (well, OK, hundred yards from here) Isiah had (if you believe Bible) had vision of angels saying the exact same thing. Talk about being in presence of history! Wow! (I apologize for not talking about spiritual elevation, etc. much here but there's nothing I can say that has not been said better by someone else).

Tuesday: Tour guide bragged about new highways around Jerusalem, thought it would get Israelis to dead sea in ? hour- sad to see Israelis making same mistakes as Atlantans, more roads leading to more sprawl etc. Of course given iffy condition of nation it may not make difference in long run.

First we went to Ramat Rachel kibbutz, south of city. Good views of desert, Bethelehem, etc. Was reall.y surprised that I could see desert from city (though collapse of my camera means I can't describe it effectively). Atop Ramat Rachel lies archaeological dig from First Temple types (600 BC or earlier). We walked around site, saw bottom of walls from what we think was ruins. Just think - on this very spot Jews may have been worshipping idols 2700 years ago. (On other hand truth may resemble sign I once saw in New Orleans: "On this spot in 1890 nothing of importance happened").

Visited Yad Vashem- only real disappointment of trip. Thought we would see full museum; instead just listened to boring speech by Israeli ambassador to Poland, and had brief service in Hall of Remembrance (dark room with names of death camps on it). Walked briefly through sculpture garden. Then we had lunch at Jerusalem Mall (not real interesting - had wretched attempt at Pad Thai), went straight to rally.

Rally was in Jewish Quarter of Old City, mostly settled in Middle Ages. Totally fascinating. Rally had about 250 paying customers, plus Israelis just hanging around. In Hurva Square, main square of Jewish Quarter. Misc. people spoke briefly. Star of show (in terms of substance) was Rabbi Shlomo Riskin, Orthodox rabbi whose email list I am on and who emigrated from NYC to Israel. Riskin said (according to my notes) that "one of the most immoral sentences ever written was turn the other cheek. And one of the most moral sentences ever written was if a man comes to kill you, kill him first." Other speakers included mother of bombing victim, Natan Sharansky (Soviet refusenik turned Israeli pol), Sen. Torricell of NJ- none of them said anything I considered memorable.

Looked through papers online the next day. Major Israeli papers had small stories on Rally; no international coverage though. Maybe next year they will do better.

Before rally learned that Israel has own conspiracy theorists: some guy was selling table full of books with titles like "Who Killed Yitzchak Rabin?" (His conclusion: Shimon Peres did it, or more specifically got his former bodyguard, who later become Rabin's bodyguard, to fire fatal shots).

Then walked through Jewish Quarter- fascinating! No obvious space for cars, though I saw one or two. Most could barely accommodate one car, and streets are maze not grid or cul de sac. Typically street pattern: each street flanked by numerous courtyards containing apts. Most residents (except richer ones) live in walkups. A few had apt entrances directly accessible from street; looked to me like latter group richer, had more space. (Not like USA where due to security concerns apt. dwellers want common entrances etc. to protect them from street crime). Lots of mini shuls, most interesting looking were Karaite synagogue (which I suspect was usually closed) and Ramban synagogues (founded by great Jewish Bible commentator Ramban, aka Nachmanides). Bought some souveniers here too of course.

So by 5:30 I remembered I had dinner date w/cousin--no vehicles inside Jewish Quarter, instead one goes to gates. So I bailed out of group, went to gate. Was tempted to take cab, but saw bus and pounced. Now you might ask "isn't it dangerous to take buses"? Tis true that terrorists do like to bomb them. But odds really pretty minimal if you are talking about just a ride or two. 1 million people board Israeli buses each day, and maybe 50 a year get blown up (100 over two years, in fact). So even if I was doing this every day my odds would be one in 20,000. But I wasn't. Real odds are 1 in 20,000 divided by 365 (about 1 in 7 million), which is very low indeed. I figured odds would be equally high of cab driver being terrorist, kidnapping me and killing me (i.e. almost zero).

I also wanted to take the bus for a couple of political reasons. First of all, I figured the bus company needed my solidarity and my money just as much as the souvenir sellers, maybe more so since it had gotten worse press. Second, as a transit activist at home I felt a special desire to support buses. (P.S. I wasn't only American riding bus either). Fare was 5.2 shekels, or about 1.25 in American dollars, cheaper than in most big American cities (Atlanta is 1.75, Buffalo 1.45, NYC 1.50)

Then I walked to Dov's apt., about a 40 minute walk. Went through relatively lush area called Talbiya, lots of street trees, cute little shops, presidential house nearby. Got sense this was upper class area. Housing stock still not that much different from rest of J, small apartment houses, probably 3 or 4 stories. President's house surrounded by walls and bushes, totally invisible from street unlike US White House. Not sure whether this improves security. At any rate, had dinner w/Dov and family and had nice time--noticed apt. a bit small, and that bathroom in separate room from shower/tub, which struck me as kind of a nuisance. Dov & his wife don't drive, but his son had car, dropped me off at hotel. I noticed that J. at night looks better than in day, in sense that lighting of signs conceals monotony of architecture (i.e. that everything brown). Noticed place named "Caf? Hillel"--amused me, because I realized that if Hillel alive today could sue for misappropriation of name.

After getting home went to supermarket to get soda, extra gifts. Price higher than in US for most but not all items. Among things I've seen in kosher shops in America, prices in US comparable to prices in Israel, instead of being higher due to import costs- I guess this means exchange rates don't favor tourists.
Again, I was happy to be supporting the non-souvenir parts of the Israeli economy - I figure most American tourists pretty much limit their spending to hotels and Judaica, hardly my idea of the perfect foundations for a viable economy. (On the other hand, I'm not sure supermarkets are any more critical).

Noticed no pay phones- there were street phones but they only accept (1) phone cards or (2) collect phones. What a pain! (I almost made a collect call to Dov when I could not find his apt within the building address he had given me- but then I remembered I had address book which had better directions)

Wed. the 13th- Began with faux pas. We (Rally visitors) mostly ate breakfast together at hotel, since it was included in price. Someone asked me what it was like to be Jew in Arkansas. Told him I had no anti-Semitism issue, but that I was slightly put off when I went to public events and heard the Jesus' name mentioned at end of prayer. I later learned that the fellow I was speaking to was a Jew for Jesus (Messianic Jews, I believe they call themselves today). Oops!

Thought about blowing off rest of group, taking bus to Yad Vashem and seeing whole place. Instead I decided to go with group; BIG mistake.

First place group went was Shaarey Zedek hospital. Incredibly nauseating and depressing; I listened to nurse talk about her experiences with suicide bombings, how some hospital staffers had had relatives die (she even brought out victim who survived one, talked about what it was like - feeling body bursting into flame, thinking this was last moment of life, praying, then being rescued),

Listening to nurse was emotional low point of trips - not just because of specific stuff she said, more the tone - I could tell she couldn't numb herself, her emotional nerve endings were totally raw. It seems to me that if you can't be desensitized to horrors of war you are probably not going to be able to win it - especially since Israelis, to a greater extent than their enemies, can always bail out and lead more comfortable lives in America. Unless there is peace soon, I feel confident in saying that that nurse will, by 2005, be either in America or in a mental hospital (assuming of course that she doesn't get blown up).

One or two things she said did grab me, and made me feel very depressed about Israel's chance of survival. She yammered about how every human life is precious; it struck me that if Americans had had that attitude in WW 2 (when, as I recall, we dispatched 100,000 each in Hiroshima and Dresden) Americans would now be speaking German and Japanese. She said war had been going on for TWO WHOLE YEARS! In Afghanistan, and probably in other places, war has gone on for 30 years and people deal with it (albeit not happily, I am sure). My spin: Israelis (and maybe even affluent societies generally) have a limited ability to handle this sort of horror; their comfort makes them soft compared to people in Third World nations like Afghanistan (though not necessarily compared to Americans). All in all, I began to wonder if Israel had much of a chance to survive if things continued in present vein.

Then we went on tour of hospital - we saw bomb shelters (now used for storage of stuff usable for chemical attacks) and parking lot (which can be used for chemical decontamination). Doctor who took us there seemed a bit less messed up than nurse, mentioned that there were occasional bombings in 70s.

While all this was going on I was getting dehydrated, starting to feel lightheaded--even though hospital inside, air conditioning was not in every corridor. I guess climate like this does not agree with me.

After all this, went to Ir David (City of David)- archaelogical site technically outside Old City, but really (according to tour guides) where Jerusalem started. Not sure whether this is supported by real archaeological evidence; guides said they identified this place based on calculations from Bible, which troubles me because relevant portions of Bible (Kings and Chronicles) probably written more for theological purposes than for historical purposes. At any rate, this area is supposedly where David built Jerusalem and made it his capitol. Every IDF soldier, after enlisting, is brought here, as if to show them: "This is why we're fighting - to preserve the Jewish state that began here." (Not sure if non-Jewish IDF soldiers brought here). Ir David was kind of a disappointment- everything we saw was reconstructed, kind of like Colonial Williamsburg. I liked the Ramat Rachel site better, it was more real, or at least looked more real--I thought I was seeing things that actually were 2800 years old (not that I really know a darn thing about it).

Then went to Hebrew University, site of last big suicide bombing. We had little service where various people (most notably embassies of Korea, Japan, USA) had sent condolence wreaths. Service was in courtyard where victims brought immediately after bombing. Rabbi gave brief speech, lit memorial candle. On the way back to tour bus I noticed Hebrew University law school, which was of course unscathed. (This fact begs for tasteless lawyer joke, I suppose - but I'm not going to be person to create it, at least not here, not now).

Interesting fact (according to tour guide, whose veracity may be iffy): 25% of slots at Hebrew Univ. reserved for Arabs.

After HU, we listened to one of Sharon's assistants yammer; man spoke very well but was totally self-contradictory. On one hand, he vowed to bring terrorists to justice. On the other, he said that if Israel just "isolated" Arafat, maybe he'd go away (and presumably be replaced by someone nicer, ha ha ha). I was filled with contempt for Israeli politicians after listening to him - thought they had no idea what they were doing. But to be fair they may be in impossible situation; they might be afraid of wrath of USA if they played by USA type rules (i.e. bombing the hell out of Arabs till their cities are total rubble a la Dresden or Hiroshima). He said Israel "presenting a model of a fighting democracy", "democracy has a future", urged us to move to Israel. Unfortunately, none of these comments made me more hopeful.

Wed. night was more uplifting by far. Forgot about politics, went to wedding of distant cousin (who lived in Hebron, I think) south of city with cousin Dov- first Orthodox wedding I had ever been to (actually only 4th wedding I had been to in life, unless there are weddings I have been to as kid and forgot about). Took bus to wedding- that seemed to be what Dov wanted, and I sure wasn't going to more of a wuss than my 70 something cousin (plus as a foreigner, I figured I wasn't knowledgeable enough to exercise my own judgment if I had a native to defer to). Very different in a variety of ways from what I was used to:

*Almost nobody wearing a tie. I saw no tuxes, 2 men wearing dark suits (one from St. Louis, one was groom's father), 3 or 4 others (myself included) in sport coats and ties. Groom wore open white shirt and white robe (called a kittel) over it. Most people didn't even tuck in shirt; dominant uniform untucked white shirt.

*So many guests with long hair and beards (more likely Hasids than Hippies) that I thought I was at a Jesus impersonators convention. (In fact, I thought bride's father looked roughly like Jesus would look like if he had lived to be 50 and was balding and wearing glasses).

*Groom walked down steps, accompanied by men playing music. Rabbi (also no tie) said something in Hebrew (I think reciting marriage contract terms), various other people said other stuff in Hebrew (I think prayers). Then we sat down and ate.

*No coed dancing- men dance with men in long circle, women with women. I participated. (Dov later explained that this was customary in Orthodox weddings, but it was not "ultra-Orthodox"--at ultra-Orthodox weddings, men and women don't just dance in separate rooms, they eat in separate rooms).

Met numerous distant relatives, whom I liked in varying degrees.

Thurs, the 15th- Began day with intense weirdness. Sat at hotel breakfast table with various missionaries, Jews for Jesus, etc. (they were only people in hotel restaurant at time). They were all anoiting each other with olive oil; I accepted this not to be rude, but wiped it off as soon as I went to the buffet table since I suspected that even though I wasn't enough of a Talmud scholar to KNOW it wasn't appropriate, I guessed that I was on the wrong side of a line here. Then they started debating whether they wanted Third Temple to come or not; one said yes because it was necessary for Christ to come again, another said no because she did not like animal sacrifices and because Antichrist might come. Rather than presenting the Jewish perspective, I thought this would be an excellent time to declare self finished.

Read Israeli papers (or English language edition of same) in morning: saw poll that 50% of Palestinians Arabs optimistic about future, only 30% pessimistic. (By contrast, Israelis less optimistic- obviously Arabs think they are winning). Same poll showed when asked who was winning, Israelis split evenly about "us", "the Arabs", and "no one." My interpretation: Arabs think that if they randomly murder enough Jews without fear of collective retaliation, Jews will get demoralized and move. Nothing convinced me that they are wrong.

Then walked to Yehid Moshe, first Jewish area outside Old City (built in 1840s by British philanthropist). Red roofs, so only hint of non-brown color in J. housing. Very comfortable looking area- lots of small gardens outside apts. (not as good as Buffalo gardens to be sure, but climate not great for gardening I guess). Still apartments rather than detached houses. Housing in courtyards; people had cars but they were all in parking lot far from apts. - J. very much a walking city, as you can guess (though lots of jerks park on sidewalk).

Saw Old City from Yehid Moshe- walked up, discovered Armenian Quarter. I walked about a block, was set upon by would-be tour guides in search of my money. Decided that since I had to leave for airport in a couple of hours and was running out of shekels, I had neither the time nor the $ for this sort of thing, so I quickly bailed out. Based on my Guidebook, Armenian Quarter wasn't all that interesting anyhow- general urban design seemed pretty much same as Jewish Quarter.

Then walked towards hotel, tried to think of something interesting I could see in last hour or two. Went to Skirball Museum (tiny archaeological museum near Reform rabbinical seminary) and saw a few artifacts from Biblical times. Most interesting- a "victory stele" by some local pagan king talking about how he defeated and killed king of Israel (northern kingdom of Isreal) and of "house of David." (presumably southern kingdom, covered southern half of what is now Israel) Bible says, by contrast, same two kings were killed by palace coup. Wonder who's lying? I suspect pagan- he might have defeated them in battle, claimed to have killed them just to brag. But I guess we will never know. At any rate, this stele does corroborate that these kingdoms existed.

Also saw idols from territory of Jewish tribe Dan. Concrete evidence of idolatry, or just evidence that pagans lived nearby? I guess we will never know.

Then went to airport- much less security on way back than on way to Israel. El Al equally careful re checking checked bags, but didn't make us take off sport coats or even empty pockets (by contrast, at LaGuardia you have to empty ALL pockets and take off shoes twice). Sat next to American turned Israeli on flight; my sense was that war had pretty much gotten to her hard--bolstered my lack of confidence in Israel's fighting spirit. Got home to NYC Thursday night, spent night w/friend, came home Friday night.

Overall, glad I went.

Posted by lewyn at 2:48 PM EST
old Atlanta Jewish Times articles

IS AMERICA FACING ITS OWN TISHA'B'AV? (8-22-03)
Jews throughout the world recently fasted and prayed on Tisha'b'Av (the 9th Day of Av). On that day, the First and Second Temples were destroyed and Jews later suffered a wide variety of other misfortunes.
Centuries after the destruction of the Temples, traditional commentators asserted that Jews loss of the Temples was divine punishment for various sins. But a geopolitical explanation also exists: The loss of both Temples arose from our ancestors attempts to stand up to a powerful foreign empire.
In the 6th century B.C.E., the Jewish king Zedekiah, a vassal of the Babylonian Empire, rebelled against what he probably perceived as oppression. And Babylon responded by wiping out the Jewish kingdom, destroying the First Temple and sending almost all the Jews into exile in Babylon.
Six and a half centuries later, first-century Jews in Israel were sick and tired of corrupt, brutal Roman governors. So they rose up against the Roman Empire - and like Zedekiah, they were crushed. The Romans destroyed the Second Temple and killed or enslaved millions of Jews.
After another anti-Roman rebellion yielded similarly tragic results, Jews moved towards a more pacifist posture for many centuries, tolerating gentile repression rather than taking up arms.
Both supporters and opponents of Americas adventures in Iraq can invoke these TishabAv wars as precedent. My hawkish friends argue: Just as ancient Jews got crushed for resisting the Babylonian and Roman Empires, the Taliban and Sadaam Hussein have been crushed for resisting the United States.
Hence, Arabs and radical Muslims in other countries will learn to make nice with America just as Jews learned to make nice with Rome.
So far, of course, this strategy has been of limited value: the destruction of Iraq's government has not prevented well-armed civilians (from Iraq and from other nations) from attacking Americans.
And as long as America, unlike Rome, seeks to minimize civilian casualties, our empire will never exterminate most of its enemies.
Indeed, a sophisticated dove could argue that just as ancient Jews provoked the Babylonian and Roman Empires, America's Iraq adventure has foolishly provoked the "empire" of Islamic terrorism.
We already know that the Iraq war has increased Muslim hostility to the United States. For example, a recent Pew Center poll reported that 77 percent of Moroccans held a favorable opinion of America in 1999 - but only 27 percent do today.
A worst-case scenario is as follows: Some of the most [newly] hostile Muslims become full-time terrorists. And the more people who start new terrorist groups or join existing ones, the more likely it is that some of those terrorists will succeed in attacking Americans or obtaining weapons of mass destruction.
Eventually, a group of these terrorists gets the smallpox virus or a few nuclear weapons -- and America suffers its own TishabAv.
So which scenario is correct? Will the Iraq war force Arab radicals to live in peace with America? Or is Americas assault upon Sadaam & Co. going to risk Americas own destruction by provoking terrorism?
Ten years elapsed between Osama bin Laden's initial radicalization (caused, so he claims, by Americas decision to post troops in Saudi Arabia in 1991) and his attack on the World Trade Center. So it may take 10 years or more to learn the long-term results of Americas recent wars.

MUSLIMS, POLLS AND MYTHS (7-4-03)

A few weeks ago, the Pew Global Attitudes Project (www.people-press.org), part of Washingtons Pew Center think tank, issued the results of a poll taken in dozens of countries, including several Arab and Muslim countries. Thel results conflict with myths cherished by hawk and dove alike.

For example, one common dovish myth is that most Muslims just want to get along with us infidels, and that only a few crazy people support al-Qaeda and other terrorist groups.
But the Pew Center poll suggests otherwise. When asked how much confidence they had in a variety of world leaders, 71 percent of Palestinians stated that they have a lot or some confidence in Osama bin Laden, as did 58 percent of Indonesians and 55 percent of Jordanians.

In Pakistan, where the local dictator supports (or at least pretends to support) American anti-terror efforts, 45 percent of respondents supported bin Laden, and only half of the other 55 percent did not. The rest refused to answer, no doubt because they feared government retaliation.

In no Islamic country did over 30 percent of respondents favor U.S.-led efforts to fight terrorism.

Muslim attitudes towards Israel are even more Neanderthal. When they were asked whether Arab needs can be taken care of as long as the state of Israel exists, 80 percent of Palestinians, 85 percent of Jordanians and 90 percent of Moroccans answered in the negative, essentially endorsing the extermination of Israel.
The moderate Muslim states were not much better. Supporters of wiping out Israel outnumbered supporters of a two-state solution by 57 percent to 23 percent in Pakistan, 58 percent to 28 percent in Indonesia, and 49 percent to 33 percent in Turkey.

By contrast, 74 percent of French respondents said that a way can be found for the State of Israel to exist so that the rights and needs of the Palestinian people can be [addressed]." In America and Israel, 67 percent agreed.

The Pew Center poll also explodes the hawkish myth that Muslim public opinion is so fixed that it cannot be affected by U.S. policy. In fact, public opinion of America has changed dramatically for the worse in Muslim nations over the past few years.

For example, 77 percent of Moroccans held a favorable opinion of America in 1999 - but only 27 percent do today. In Indonesia, U.S. supporters plunged from 75 percent in 1999 to 61 percent in 2002 to 15 percent today. In Turkey, the percentage of pro-U.S. respondents skidded from 52 percent in 1999 to 30 percent in 2002 to 15 percent in 2003.

Even the most anti-American areas have hardened their views. In 1999, 14 percent of the Palestinian Authoritys residents held a favorable opinion of America; today only 1 percent do. When Americans make war upon Muslim countries, yesterday's friends become today's foes.

This poll also contradicts the pro-war argument that America's takeover of Iraq will cause the Arabs to love us because Sadaam Hussein was so awful. In fact, only 4 percent of Palestinians, 17 percent of Indonesians and Pakistanis, 19 percent of Jordanians, and 24 percent of Morrocans believe that Iraqis are better off now.

If you're an optimistic, you can argue those numbers show that Muslim opinion of America can only improve. If you're a realist, you know we have to find a way to do better.
[NOTE: this last paragraph of the above article differs pretty significantly from what I wrote].

AMERICA'S TAXING SITUATION (6-20-03)

About 1,800 years ago, our sages wrote in the Mishnah: "Pray for the welfare of the government, for without fear of it, people would swallow each other alive."

Today, our government is less wasteful and repressive than the Roman Empire under which the Mishnahs authors lived. Nevertheless, many Americans would rather eviscerate government than pray for its welfare. At the federal level, Congress just voted to cut taxes even though the government is already mired in debt.

And at the state and local level, many governments are broke, partially because of the economic slowdown and partially because Congress continues to enact unfunded mandates - laws that require, say, better education for disabled children or increased homeland security without giving the states money to fund such projects.

The federal government won't help, and many voters would rather see state and local governments chopped to ribbons than forego tax cuts.

Why? Because many voters believe that starving the government will lead us to paradise; we will all painlessly finance tax cuts by eliminating government waste, fraud and abuse.

But this argument is based on a fallacy. Taxophobes believe that if government is adequately financed, politicans are not wise enough to spend the money intelligently. But they also believe that if government is underfinanced, those same politicians are wise enough to cut wasteful spending instead of essential government functions. Obviously, both propositions cannot be true.

The authors of the Mishnah, by contrast, didn't think that weak government led to a low-tax utopia. Instead, they wrote that weak government leads to anarchy- and thats exactly what is happening in parts of America.

Local governments starved for revenue are balancing their budget by cutting back on police, prosecutors, and prisons. For example:

*In Kentucky, a budget crisis forced the early release of 900 prisoners, some of whom were promptly rearrested on rape, robbery and other charges.

* In Minneapolis, the police department has shaved 200 officers from a 900-person force, partially because the state cut funding, partially because the federal government reduced subsidies for local police, and partially because the federal government has forced local police to busy themselves guarding waterworks against terrorism instead of addressing more common crimes.

*And in Portland, Oregon, the county prosecutors office shrank by more than 20 percent and the police budget was cut by more than 10 percent in the last three years. At the same time, the federal government is requiring the police department to spend millions of dollars to guard bridges.

The results of Portland's "pro-crime" policies are predictable: in the first four months of 2003 alone, car thefts have risen 19 percent and home burglaries have jumped by 21 percent

Atlantans have been spared the worst of taxophobia, primarily because Governor Perdue chose an increase in tobacco taxes over cuts in public safety.

But should the states fiscal problems continue next year, Georgians may face a tougher set of fiscal choices, so how can we avoid Portland's fate?

First, tell Gov. Perdue and Mayor Franklin to keep up the good work, and urge our legislators to focus on preserving the most important public services as well as on keeping taxes down.
Second, tell Congress to support state and local governments instead of obstructing their work with unfunded mandates.


THE POLITICS OF RUTH (5-30-03)
On Shavuot, Jews around the world read the Book of Ruth, which begins when a Jewish couple (Naomi and Elimelech) leave Bethlehem and move to pagan Moab because of a famine. They marry their sons off to Moabite women, but Elimelech and the sons die.

When Naomi returns to Israel, one of her daughters-in-law, Ruth, comes with her, converts to Judaism, and marries a Jew. (She later bears King David's grandfather). But the Book of Ruth is not just a G-related soap opera; it's a story laden with messages for today.

When Naomi's husband and sons die in Moab, she has no visible means of support -- no one to provide for her and no form of social welfare or communal charity in Moab.

Moab is the perfect libertarian society: Each person is responsible for herself and the local idol-worshippers are unburdened by a welfare state or taxes [to support one]. There is no place for the likes of Naomi in Moab.

Fortunately, Naomi hears that the regional famine is over in Israel. After she and Ruth go there, Ruth "came and gleaned in a field behind the reapers (2:3). In plain English, Ruth went on someone else's farm and gathered grain to eat.

Nevertheless, Ruth is not a thief. She is merely taking her due under Torah law, which states:
"When you reap the harvest of your land, you shall not reap all the way to the edges of your field, or gather the gleanings of your harvest, you shall leave them for the poor and the stranger." [Leviticus 23:22].

In other words, the Torah mandates an agricultural version of the modern welfare state. Instead of adopting the libertarian position that every person is responsible for herself, the Torah says everyone is entitled to some minimal amount of material support, and that every non-poor farmer must provide that support by leaving gleanings of your harvest . . . for the poor and the stranger.

Todays conservative conventional wisdom is that the hard-working taxpayer owes nobody anything because "it's your money" and that no one can tell you what to do with your land.

But the Torah operates on the assumption that the hard-working farmer owes the poor something because the land ultimately belongs not to the farmer but to our divine creator. The recipient of such social welfare has obligations too. She can't just sit at her mailbox and watch the welfare checks roll in; she has to go out and pick up her grain.

In effect, the Torah creates not a welfare state of subsidized idleness, but a workfare state where those who are willing to work for their food are entitled to support from Hebrew farmers.

Like any great literature, the Book of Ruth raisew as many questions as answers. We know from Ruth that we have an obligation to support the poor and the stranger. But how does this obligation function in a society where Jews are a minority? Are Jews merely obligated to provide charity among themselves and ignore the rest of society?

Or are we obligated to urge other Americans to provide charity collectively through our government?

And if we are, exactly what must our government do for the poor and the stranger?

Is it enough to give the poor some food and give their children a minimal education? Or must we provide health insurance and other services that you or I might deem necessary for a normal life? The Torah may not provide a clear answer but it encourages us to ask the questions.

CYNTHIA TUCKER AND ISRAEL (5-9-03)

Recent issues of the Jewish Times have hosted an exchange of letters about Cynthia Tucker, editor of the Atlanta Journal-Constitutions editorial page. One letter praised Tucker for her "keen insight into the Israeli-Palestinian conflict" while others blamed her for what they perceive to be the paper's anti-Israel bias.

I decided to go on the Internet to find out what Tucker really thinks of Israel.

Much to my surprise, I found only one or two Israel-related columns by Tucker herself over the past several years (as opposed to columns by other writers or by the Journal-Constitutions editorial board, which represents the perspectives o a collective of journalists).

Tuckers most relevant column, dated April 7, 2002, focused on death threats heaped upon the family of Adam Shapiro, a self-styled peace activist from Brooklyn who decided to visit Palestinian Authority Yasser Arafat while his compound in Ramallah was under siege by the Israeli army.

Tucker understandably denounced the threats to Shapiro's family, but didn't take the further step of endorsing Shapiro's breakfasts with Arafat as a step towards peace. Instead, she noted that Israel's supporters have long denounced Arafat and the terrorism that he has, at the very least, tolerated.
She further wrote that pro-Israel threat-mongers were behaving like Palestinian extremists who are well known for their intolerance of anyone labeled a `colloborator.

She explained: Palestinians believed to be cooperating with Israeli authorities are often treated to mob justice brutal beatings, summary executions, anonymous graves. Is that not what the Shapiros critics are also threatening?

In other words, Tucker does not assert that Arafat is just a nationalist leader and that suicide bombers are merely "frustrated" and "misunderstood"; instead, she apparently thinks Arafat is a thug and that his followers are worse.

Tucker has also condemned American supporters of Arab extremism.

In a June 30, 2002 article about Cynthia McKinneys fight for re-election, she described her [McKinney] as a fringe lunatic, well outside the congressional mainstream and incapable of aiding any cause, whether an independent Palestine or her own congressional district. (McKinney ultimately lost in a campaign exacerbated by anti-Semitic remarks made by her father, Billy McKinney).

But Tucker is not a firm supporter of the Israeli government. She wrote that Prime Minister Ariel Sharon's heavy-handed tactics have started to corrode the decency, humanity and moral authority of the nation he seeks to defend.

Tucker explained: While the targets of Israeli tanks and commandoes are often well-armed extremists of Hamas and Hezbollah, the targets are also, too often, young boys armed only with rocks and bottles - rhetoric that may have made sense a decade ago, but is out of date when many Arab boys prefer blowing people up to bottle throwing.

So, we conclude from all of this that Tucker is not a rabid McKinneyite foe of Israel, but a more moderate liberal: She doesnt like Israels enemies, but she doesnt want Israel to be too tough either.

That makes her the sort of liberal who swoons over former Prime Minister Shimon Peres rather than the sort of liberal who thinks both Peres and Sharon are both war criminals.

SECULARISM: GOOD FOR THE JEWISH PEOPLE? (4-25-03)

As Jews argue about whether they should be aligned with social liberals or Christian conservatives, they tell each other two very different stories.

The liberal, secularist story is based primarily on one simple fact: For more than 1500 years, Jews lived in a Christian-dominated Europe, one where most countries had established state churches.

And for many of those years, European Christians served our ancestors with heaping helpings of anti-Semitism, culminating in the Holocaust.

Social liberals reason that to avoid such unappetizing dishes, Jews should fight for liberal social mores generally and strict separation of church and state in particular.

For example, Michael Staub, a professor at Bowling Green State University writes: "Given the deeply racist, and often anti-Semitic cast of Christian culture and history it strikes me as odd . . . to ascribe our success in the U.S. to Christianity."

The conservatives' story is based on Jews' experiences today -- not just with Christian conservatives and their support for Israel, but more broadly on the differences between America and Europe.

America is far more religious than other affluent democracies. For example, a 1998 survey by the University of Michigan showed that 44 percent of Americans attended church once a week, as opposed to only 27 percent of British, 21 percent of French, and 4 percent of Swedes.

Americans attitudes are also more religious: An early 1990s survey by the University of Chicago shows that one-third of Americans view the Bible as the actual word of God as opposed to 7 percent of British, 12 percent of West Germans, and 12 percent of Austrians.

If Christian fundamentalism was bad for Judaism, America would be more anti-Semitic (and perhaps more anti-Israel) than Europe. But this is clearly not the case. By most measures, America is friendlier to Jews than Europe: Anti-Semitism is less common, and Americans are far more pro-Israel than most Europeans.
So the conservative argument runs as follows: Religious Christians are more pro-Jewish and pro-Israel than everyone else, and religious America is more pro-Jewish and pro-Israel than secular Europe. Thus, Christian conservatism is good for the Jews.

As the right-wing rabbi Daniel Lapin argues, "America's Bible belt is the Jewish safety belt and Jews who disregard this fact are driv[ing] with their eyes on the rear view mirror instead of the windshield."

But this has not always been the case. For example, the America of the 1930s was a more religious, conservative country than the America of 2003 -- prayer in public schools was common and abortion and homosexuality were [often] illegal. So if publicly endorsed fundamentalism was good for the Jews, 1930s America should have been paradise. Yet in fact, the religiously conservative America of 60 years ago was more anti-Semitic than todays America in many ways.

A 1937 Gallup poll revealed that 51 percent of Americans would never vote for a Jew for president, and a 1938 poll showed that 58 percent of Americans believed that European persecution of Jews was at least partially their [Jews'] own fault.

And when German Jews sought to flee Hitler, conservative Christian America kept them out.

In 1939, Senator Robert Wagner (D-N.Y.) and Representative Edith Rogers (D-Mass.) introduced a bill to admit 10,000 refugee children into America. But the bill was crushed -- not by liberal secular humanists but by isolationists and right-leaning veterans groups.

Opponents of the bill included the Veterans of Foreign Wars, the American Legion, the Daughters of the American Revolution, and the Daughers of the Confederacy. The bills congressional supporters were disproportionately from the urban, socially liberal Northeast, while most of its opponents were conservatives.

Today, America's religious conservatism seems to lead to good interfaith relationships. But 70 years ago, this was not the case. The most logical conclusion from these facts is that Jews have no permanent allies or permanent enemies, but only permanent interests.

MORDECAI Q. PUBLIC'S PURIM (4-4-03)

For most of my life, I thought that Purim was about wearing funny costumes, making noise while the Book of Esther is being read, and eating triangular pastries. But in recent years, I have learned that other Purim customs include:
*Drinking on Purim night to the extent that one no can longer fully differentiate between cursed is Haman and blessed is Mordecai.
*Giving gifts of food to as many friends and acquaintances as possible.
*Giving gifts to the poor.

In the small, mixed-income Jewish towns and neighborhoods of the 19th and early 20th centuries, these customs were easy to follow. Mordecai Q. Public could get have a few drinks on Purim night and stagger home, get up in the morning, give some money or food to a couple of poor neighbors and spend the rest of the day distributing sweets to friends.

But in America's suburban metropolis[es], most of these customs have withered away. Imagine, if you will, a 21st-century Mordecai Q. Public who lives and works in a Atlanta suburb.

Mordecai begins the holiday by resolving to have a few drinks on Purim night at the neighborhood synagogue. But right away our would-be celebrant runs into trouble he probably can't reach the synagogue without driving, which means he can't drink on Purim without endangering numerous lives.

And why can't Mordecai walk to shul? Because in much of metropolitan Atlanta, zoning laws allow only a house or two on each acre of land (or 650-1,300 houses per square mile). This means that only 150 or 300 houses will be within a quarter-mile walk of a synagogue.

If the area near the synagogue has as few Jews as the rest of metro Atlanta (about 2-3 percent of the population), some synagogues may have as few as five or 10 Jewish neighbors.

In other words, Atlanta's suburbs are typically so thinly populated that hardly anyone lives within walking distance of a synagogue.

And even if Mordecai lived within walking distance of a synagogue, he could not do so in safety and comfort because many of the residential streets lack sidewalks.

But suppose our adventurous friend, with or without alcohol, wakes up the next morning and resolves to fulfill the Purim custom of giving to poor people. If he works downtown, near panhandler-heavy Woodruff Park, this good deed is easily performed.

Otherwise, Mordecai is out of luck; Atlantans have so effectively segregated wealth and poverty that the average suburban office park has no denizens who will admit to needing charity.

The custom of giving food to friends is also not easily satisfied in suburbia. Here too the culprit is low density: if all your Jewish friends live a 45-minute drive from each other, there simply is not enough time to speed to Five Points to help the poor, drive an hour into suburbia to drop goodies off for friend A, then drive half an hour more to drop goodies off for friend B and still squeeze in a workday.

So if Atlanta's sprawl prevents grownups from drinking, charity, and exchanging gifts on Purim, what's left of the holiday? Noisemakers and costumes- in other words, a holiday thats fun for kids but not particularly interesting for adults. And thats how Purim become infantil[ized].




THE CASE AGAINST THE SLIPPERY SLOPE (2-28-03)

In recent years, the Christian right has been one of Israel's most loyal supporters. For example, former Christian Coalition leader Ralph Reed has joined a rabbi in Stand for Israel, a group formed to mobilize 100,000 evangelical churches to raise money and support for Israel.

Yet many Jews are hostile to the religious right at least partially because of concerns over church-state separation.

For example, one American Jewish Congress (AJC) fundraising letter states: "If you and I are not vigilant, the religious right may be able to achieve . . . a government where those who do not share their religious views are, in effect, second-class citizens."

While mainstream Jewish groups constantly seek to improve relations with African-Americans and other traditionally liberal groups, the same groups are rigidly opposed to any breach in the alleged wall between church and state, oblivious to the danger that repeated slights could endanger Christian conservatives support for Israel.

Jewish support for church-state separation is not completely irrational. Clearly, some varieties of public support for religion, such as openly Christian prayers at government functions, do trample on Jewish sensitivities.

And other church-state issues raise practical concerns. For example, one common argument against vouchers for parochial school students is that such aid might drain funds from public schools.

But Jewish concerns often rest on a broader and less rational phobia --the slippery slope idea exemplified by an Anti-Defamation League press release: "Supreme Court Decision on Public Aid to Parochial Schools Could Lead to a Slippery Slope On Church-State Separation."

This press release was hardly an aberration: I ran a Internet search and found 374 references incorporating the phrases "church-state" and "slippery slope".

The concern here is that any accommodation of religion in any public facility or institution will inevitably lead America on a slippery slope towards a Christian theocracy.
The flaw in the "slippery slope" argument is this: Religious activity has never been completely separated from government facilities.

For example, if you watch Congressional proceedings on C-SPAN you might notice that Congress begins with an invocation by a clergyman.

And if you buy breakfast or a snack on the way to work you might notice that the government-issued cash you spend includes the phrase "In God We Trust".

And if you have college-age children, they can use federal Pell Grants or student loans to attend religious as well as secular institutions.

And if your children go to public high school, they may be able to join a Torah study group meeting at the school (if the school extends similar privileges to secular student groups).
And on Shabbos, you might pray at a synagogue which is tax-exempt.

In fact, many of the same Jewish groups that seek to guard church-state separation also endorse some forms of aid to religious institutions. The AJCs Statement on Church-State Relations endorses publicly funded benefits, such as lunches and medical and dental services [for] all school children and loans to parochial schools to assist them in complying with federal health and safety standards.

In sum, American government is already intertwined with religion so if any breach in the wall of church-state separation led to theocracy, America would have long ago reached the bottom of that particular slippery slope.

Does this mean we should give the Christian right a blank check to mix church and state?
Of course not. But when confronted with a controversy over government support for religion, Jews and Jewish groups should ask themselves two questions:

*Is the particular [scheme at] issue offensive to our sensibilities as Jews and as Americans?
*Will this issue endanger our relationships with Christian conservatives, and if so, is it important enough to justify creating such friction?

2050: THREE SCENARIOS FOR THE JEWISH FUTURE (2-7-03)

Not long ago, I was chatting with a friend about the state of American Jewry. My friend spouted the conventional wisdom that American Jews are becoming less numerous and more devout because liberal and secular Jews are assimilating or producing smaller families, while more religious Jews (the Orthodox [Jews] in particular) are marrying and creating large families.
Similarly, if current immigration patterns continue, Jews outside America will continue to migrate to Israel as their communities in Europe and Latin America decline.
That would mean a Jewish world dominated by a huge community in Israel and a smaller -- possibly more devout -- community in the United States.
But current patterns of Jewish life might not continue at all for one reason: terrorism. Al-Qaida wants to wipe Jews from the earth, while Hamas and its ilk seek the more modest goal of turning the land of Israel into Muslim turf.
It's conceivable that terrorist groups could, in our lifetime, obtain enough firepower to make atttacks like the September 11 disaster as regular as suicide bombings in Israel are today.
So what would happen to the Jews of America and Israel if terrorism becomes so widespread that life in one of those countries becomes intolerable? Three scenarios come to mind:
*Israel OK, America not so OK.
Imagine that over the next few decades, Israel becomes a less dangerous place after the Palestinians decide that blowing themselves up will never work. And suppose that America continues to be Public Enemy No. 1 in the Arab and Muslim-dominated world.
In that case, radical Muslims might leave Israel alone and attack America again and again with increasingly lethal weapons, causing Jews to abandon America for Eretz Yisrael.
If this scenario comes to pass, the long-predicted ingathering of the exiles will become reality and the Jewish world of 2100 will look a lot like the Jewish world of 3,000 years ago.
*America OK, Israel not so OK.
The situation in Israel continues to deteriorate, while America somehow makes peace with the Muslim world. If the Jewish state survives, it becomes less attractive to all but the most determined Jews, and millions of Israelis move to America, the new center of world Jewry.
And because the most secular Jews will likely be the first to abandon Israel, the American Jewish community of 2050 could be larger -- yet less devout -- than the American Jewish community of 2000.
*Israel not OK, America not OK.
The American-Israeli alliance, along with American wars against radical Islam and Islamic rogue states, inflames a billion Muslims and both countries become war zones.
In such a situation, many Jews might abandon both America and Israel. But where could they go?
Certainly not to Western Europe, which has becoming increasingly Muslim (and thus dangerous for Jews) in recent years due to immigration and declining birthrates among non-Muslim Europeans. And not to Latin America, which has more Muslims than Jews, and is suffering from severe economic problems.
If my nightmare scenario comes to pass, Jews would want to move to countries that either have almost no Muslims or are run by regimes so oppressive and so stable that Islamic radicalism is crushed.
The largest country that meets both criteria is China, where the Muslim population is small and the government is unlikely to tolerate dissent.
And the first criterion is met by Poland, Lithuania and the Ukraine, which have no significant Muslim population. [NOTE: Initial draft referred to Eastern Europe generally, though I'm not sure this edit makes a difference].
Although those countries (once the center of world Jewry) have a vibrant tradition of anti-Semitism, Jews may decide that the risk of harassment by Christian anti-Semities is better [less dangerous] than [the risk of] being blown up by jihadniks.

If so, the world of 2050 might look a lot like the world of 1850, one where the Western Hemisphere is no longer a center of Jewish life, but where Eastern Europe once again contains a wall of yiddishkeit from sea to shining sea.

MAKING A CASE FOR VOUCHERS (1-24-03)

(NOTE: This headline was not my idea).

Opponents of vouchers and similar programs in the Jewish community and elsewhere often claim that public schools are uniquely valuable
They argue that public schools force children of all races and classes to mix, exposing them to the real world.
Thus, only public schools deserve public support, and children whose parents cannot afford private school tuition must attend such schools.
For example, the website of the Religious Action Center (Reform Judaisms social action lobby) describes government-run schools as the heart of American identity, calling them a unifying factor among the large range of ethnic and religious communities in our society.
Such reverence for public schools obviously discourages families from sending their children to Jewish day schools. More important[ly], the claim that public schools expose children to diversity is often factually incorrect. In segregated metropolitan areas such as Atlanta, public schools have failed to expose rich to poor or whites to blacks. Instead, most public schools are dominated by one racial or demographic group.
Only 7 percent of students in Atlanta public schools are white, while 89 percent are black. By contrast, many suburban public schools are mostly white, while others are majority black but have a more affluent student body than city schools.
The status quo is quite recent: As late as 1958, only 33 percent of Atlantas public school students were black. But in the 1960s and 1970s, the federal courts tried to desegregate public schools.
As a result, many white parents decided that racially integrated schools were bad and moved en masse to majority-white suburbs. [Editors deleted sentence explaining why this was so- partially irrational, partially fears of violence, partially fears of classes being dumbed down].
But when blacks move to a suburb, it [that suburb] often becomes unpopular with whites. For example, Cleveland Heights, Ohio, was once a white suburb. But when middle-class blacks began moved in, the public schools got a bad reputation.
Today, Cleveland Heights is nearly half-black and resembles Atlantas intown neighborhoods: It retains singles and Orthodox families who send their children to religious schools, but is unpopular with other whites because of the allegedly inferior public schools.
Similarly, public schools in Atlantas more integrated suburbs tend to have few white students.
The public school system enforces -- rather than reduces -- segregation. Heres why:
If there were no public schools, many white and black middle-class families might find [intown] middle-class areas like Virginia-Highlands as attractive as the suburbs because [perceived] school quality would not factor in their housing decisions.
But as matters now stand, to stay intown parents must send their children to public schools with socially diverse student bodies and the bad reputations that often accompany such diversity. Thats a price few parents will pay.
The public school system also rewards people for becoming segregation-seeking suburbanites. A well-off suburban family can send its children to public schools and often pay lower property taxes.
Thats why vouchers might reduce housing segregation. If middle-class families could afford to send their children to private schools, many would stay intown. Therefore, more private schools would be formed, creating a virtuous cycle of urban rebirth creating new schools creating more urban rebirth.

SEEKING THE CENTER IN 2004 (12-27-02)

In 2000, President Bush got only 19 percent of the Jewish vote. Nevertheless, Jewish Republicans have been predicting in recent years that Jews would join the GOP en masse.
For example, Republican pollster Frank Luntz predicts that in 2004, George Bush will get more votes in the Jewish community since any other Republican presidential candidate since they started to measure religious voting.
Because no nationwide exit polls were taken in 2002, there is no way to tell with certainty how Jews voted in the November elections, but state polls in 2002 revealed a mixed picture.
On the one hand, Republican Gov. George Pataki of New York won a flat majority of the Jewish vote in a three-way race. But in two other states, Republican candidates were unable to improve upon the GOPs traditional share of the Jewish vote.
In California, Republican gubernatorial candidate Bill Simon got 22 percent of the Jewish vote (as opposed to 69 percent for Democrat Gray Davis and 9 percent for a leftist third party candidate).
And in New Jersey, Democratic former Sen. Frank Lautenberg pulverized Republican businessman Doug Forrester by an 80 percent- 20 percent margin among Jews.
Why was New York different from New Jersey and California? In New York, Republican George Pataki ran as [a] moderate on both economic and social issues. In addition to supporting abortion and gay rights, Pataki supported social spending [to a sufficient degree] to be endorsed by health care workers and [other government employee] unions.
By contrast, Simon ran as an anti-tax, anti-abortion, pro-gun conservative. Forrester supported legal abortion, but he also championed Bush tax cuts, opposed new gun control laws, endorsed oil drilling in the Alaska National Wildlife Reserve, and attacked federal fuel economy standards.
The lesson seems to be that a moderate Republican can win a majority of the Jewish vote, but a solid conservative will get the same 20 percent or so that got in 2000 -- and not a vote more.
Bush has focused on the concerns of his partys conservative base large tax cuts and Social Security privatization. Because conservative Republicans did as poorly among Jews in 2002 as they did in earlier elections, Bush may not exceed the GOPs traditional 20 percent share of the Jewish vote if he stays right and if the 2004 election focuses on domestic issues. But Bush can do well with Jews if he moves to the center on domestic issues.
And if foreign policy dominates the 2004 election, President Bush may gain Jewish votes for another reason. Even a conservative Republican can get a few extra Jewish votes if he is sufficiently pro-Israel or his Democratic rival is perceived as overly dovish or wishy-washy in his commitment to Israel.
In 1980, President Reagan got 39 percent of the Jewish vote against Jimmy Carter. Against the more solidly pro-Israel Walter Mondale, Reagan got 31 percent - not a stellar showing, but better than any post-Reagan Republican to date.
If Bush continues to be perceived as pro-Israel, he may get 30 percent of the Jewish vote and maybe more if the Democratic nominee is seen as too dovish by more conservative Jewish voters.
But nothing suggests that Bush can get a majority of the Jewish vote without moving to the center on domestic issues.

WHAT WOULD HAMAN DRIVE? (12-13-02)

Not long ago, a group of Christians started a What Would Jesus Drive campaign (www.whatwouldjesusdrive.org). They believe Christians should stop driving gas-guzzling vehicles because Jesus wants us to travel in ways that reduce pollution and consumption of gasoline.
I couldn't help wondering if there was a Jewish angle to this story. But rather than risking sacrilege by speculating on the likely views of long-dead Jewish prophets and scholars, I decided to imagine visiting one of Atlanta's Persian restaurants for a lunchtime interview with Haman (who, as we recall every Purim, unsuccessfully sought to wipe out the Persian Empires Jews about 2,500 years ago).
I began with the key question: Haman, what would you drive if you were alive today?
Haman: Of course, I'd drive a huge, gas-guzzling SUV or pickup truck.
Me: Why are these different from other cars?
Haman: They are gas guzzlers. Some of those cars get as little as 12 miles per gallon in city driving (as you can learn by going to www.fueleconomy.gov). And the more gasoline a car uses, the more money its drivers have to spend on oil from Arab countries. Some of that money gets sent to the enemies of the Jews in that part of the world.
Me: So gas guzzlers finance war against Israel?
Haman: Precisely - well, at least I hope so.
Me: But arent big, gas-guzzling SUVs safer than other cars precisely because they are so big?
Haman: Not so. According to a recent study [in the transportation journal published] by the University of California, the risk to drivers of average midsize and large cars is about the same [as the risk to drivers] for the [average] SUV because SUVs are so likely to roll over. Pickup trucks have even worse safety records.
And when the SUV collides with another car, the driver of the other car may get crushed. The California study also says the combined death rate (to SUV drivers and drivers of the cars they collide with} is 129 per million vehicles, as opposed to 105 for the average midsize car and even less for most minivans.
Me: Isn't the higher death rate something you're worried about?
Haman: Of course not. Just by the law of averages, some of the people hurt have to be Jews, which of course is my main goal in life - well, it would be if I was still living. Me: Do SUVs have any other benefits?
Haman: Absolutely. You ever sat behind one of those things in traffic? You can't see a thing. By blocking visibility, huge cars annoy the daylights out of other motorists - some of whom happen to be, you guessed it, Jews.
Me: But doesn't that apply to every driver?
Haman: Yes, but there are ways the careful SUV driver can target Jews. For example, I would really enjoy driving around Toco Hills on Friday in some huge car so the Jews can't get home before sundown.
Or I'd go to Quality Kosher with a car so big that it would take up two or three parking spaces.
Me: So what does your perfect car look like?
Haman: Low gas mileage and dangerous design are important, but my ideal vehicle would also have an annoyingly high center of gravity and be wide enough to take up several parking spaces. After all, the driver you're annoying may be a Jew - so happy motoring.

ONE TORAH, ONE ATLANTA (11-29-02)

In a recent election for Fulton County Commission, relations between the city of Atlanta and the rest of Fulton County became a campaign issue.
According to the Northside Neighbor, one candidate said: "If you want the city of Atlanta represented, you want [one candidate] . . . If you want the people of unincorporated Fulton represented, you want [another candidate]."
The brouhaha over these alleged remarks made me wonder what the Torah says about city-suburb relations.
One passage is arguably relevant: the requirement that Jews "shall do no unrighteousness in judgment; thou shalt not . . . favor the person of the mighty". (Leviticus 19:15).
Rashi,a medieval Torah commentator, says that this verse prohibits judges from favoring the rich. [It logically follows that] By implication, [all types of] government must provide comparable services to everyone [,rather than favoring the rich].
Yet local government falls far short of this goal. Atlantas poor are concentrated in the city and less affluent southern suburbs, while our upper middle class is concentrated in the northern suburbs. According to the 2000 Census, nearly one-quarter of Atlantas inhabitants as opposed to less than 8 percent of suburbanites lived in poverty, and Atlantas median family income is less than two-thirds that of the Atlanta region as a whole.
Because Atlanta is poorer than its suburbs, its tax base is smaller, which means that the city must choose between higher taxes and worse municipal services. Moreover, a city full of poor people must spend more money than its suburbs for the same quality of services [because poor neighborhoods require more police protection and more social spending]. And a city full of poor people typically has a smaller, less educated talent pool of politicians from which to draw, thus ensuring that less talented politicians have to do more with less.
How can be make local government more equitable? An obvious (but radical) solution is to consolidate Atlanta and its major suburbs, so that rich and poor are governed by the same mayor and council. If Atlantas four largest counties (Cobb, Gwinnett, Fulton and DeKalb) were combined, the new city would have about 2.5 million people, and be the fourth largest in the United States, making Atlanta a "major league city."
A common argument against consolidation is that [if city and suburb are consolidated] the suburbs get stuck with the city's problems. But when city and suburb combine, both prosper.
For example, in 1962 Nashville combined with Davidson County, and in one step a city of 73 square miles became a city of 473 square miles. Nashville now compares favorably with Atlanta: its population has grown by one-third since 1970 (while Atlantas has stagnated), its murder rate is one-third that of Atlanta (10 per 100,000 people as opposed to 30 per 100,000), its traffic congestion is less [overwhelming] (35 person-hours of congestion per 1,000 people, as opposed to 53 here).
As former Nashville Mayor Beverly Briley said: "I believe there is a direct relation between [consolidation] and the revitalization that downtown Nashville is experiencing."
Another argument against consolidation is that it redistributes wealth to the poor. But if this [redistribution] means higher taxes, consolidation is not redistributionist [because it does not increase the overall size of government].
Instead, narrowing the group between city and suburb requires only equal treatment a system in which the rich, poor and middle class are served and taxed by the same government, and thus get the equal service that the Torah mandates.

AN AL CHET FOR ALL OUR POLITICIANS (11-1-02)

It is appropriate that the political campaign season begins around Yom Kippur and ends with Election Dy since politicians have a lot for which to repent.
After watching a particularly reprehensible TV ad, I created a prayer to remind politicians of their campaign-season errors. Its modeled on the Al Chet prayer we say on Yom Kippur.
The politicians Al Chet would begin with the traditional opening for that prayer, which includes: Hide not Thyself from our supplication, for we are neither so arrogant nor so hardened as to say before thee, O Lord our God and God of our predecessors, `we are righteous and have not sinned; verily, we have sinned.
Then the politicians prayer would focus on sins commonly associated with liberals and those commonly associated with conservatives.
For the sin we committed by buying votes with taxpayers money, and for the sin we committed by putting future generations in debt to cut taxes today;
For the sin we committed by idolizing government, and for the sin we committed by making government the enemy;
For the sin we committed by comforting the comfortable and afflicting the afflicted;
And for the sin we committed by afflicting the middle class to make ourselves feel better;
For the sin we committed by pandering to the middle classs desire to cut its commutes by a few minutes while ignoring the working poors interest in health insurance and decent bus service;
and for the sin we committed by pretending that government could help the poor by forcing everyone to pay each other higher wages;
For the sin we committed by pretending schools could be saved by throwing money at them,
and for the sin we committed by ignoring differences between rich and poor schools;
For the sin we committed by unchastity, and for the sin we committed by focusing on our opponents personal lives;
For the sin we committed by veiled appeals to racism and [for the sin we committed by] frivolous accusations of racism;
For the sin we committed by letting government support illegitimate childbirth and the sin we committed by pretending all government spending goes to unpopular programs like welfare and foreign aid;
For the sin we committed by refusing to acknowledge that an embryo in a test tube is different than an already born human, and for the sin we committed by refusing to acknowledge that a fetus with arms, legs and a heart is different from an embryo in a test tube;
For the sins we committed by ignoring the environment;
For the sin we committed by war-mongering and by using patriotism to justify every war,
For the sin we committed by spurning the insights of religion, and for the sin we committed by using religious issues to distract voters from issues that their daily lives;
For the sin we committed by accepting bribes disguised as campaign contributions,
For the sin we committed by reckless partisanship and slandering our opponents,
For the sins we committed by pandering to labor unions; and for the sins we committed by pandering to business;
For the sins we committed in the name of liberty, and for the sins we committed in the name of equality;
For all these, O God of forgiveness, forgive us, pardon us, grant us atonement.

And to all candidates, I say what I say to myself as the gates of prayer close: Please try to do better next year.


IS THE TORAH LIBERAL OR CONSERVATIVE? BOTH (10-4-02)

As Election Day approaches, liberals and conservatives alike will clog the pages of Jewish weeklies across the nation, arguing that if we Jews properly understood our heritage, we would give our votes to the right (or left) candidate.
Liberals will emphasize Jewish traditions benevolence towards societys underdogs, while conservatives will emphasize the Torahs endorsement of a stern moral code.
So is the Torah liberal or conservative? It's both.
On cultural issues, the Torah (for the purposes of this column I mean the Five Books of Moses, not the entire Hebrew Bible or the "Oral Torah" of rabbinic interpretation) generally supports positions commonly considered conservative in 21st-century America.
For example, the Torah states: "One that strikes a man, so that he dies, shall surely be put to death." (Exodus 21:12) [Artscroll translation]. Indeed, the Torah endorses capital punishment for offenses other than murder, such as kidnapping (Exodus 21:16).
I note, however, that the severity of the Torahs rules has been diluted in a variety of ways by rabbinic interpretation.
Nor is the Torahs law-and-order tendency mitigated by a desire to protect defendants from disadvantaged backgrounds. Instead, the Torah states: "you shall not favor the poor and you shall not honor the great." (Leviticus 19:15).
Although church-state separation has become an obsession among modern Jewish liberals, the Torahs frequent endorsement of criminal penalties suggests that the Torah originally contemplated a theocratic state, one in which Jewish law could be enforced through criminal punishment.
The Torahs sexual mores also fall on the right side of todays political spectrum: in addition to condemning incest and bestiality, it appears to condemn male homosexuality, stating: "You shall not lie with a man as one lies with a woman; it is an abomination." (Leviticus 18:22).
Traditional rabbinic commentators later forbade lesbianism as well, although no Biblical provision directly addresses the issue.
On foreign policy, the Torah appears hawkish, mandating uncompromising warfare against some pagan tribes. For example, Numbers 33:5 states "you shall drive out all the inhabitants of the Land before you." And in these wars, the Torah is not always persnickety about civilian casualties: Moses states of one pagan tribe: "we destroyed every populated city . . . we did not leave a survivor." (Deuteronomy 2:34).
Thus, the modern notion that we should allow terrorists to live because there might be civilians in their midst is hard to square with some parts of the Torah.
On economic issues, however, the Torah is undoubtedly liberal by the standards of 21st-century America. Some modern right-wingers believe that "redistribution" (as in "redistribution of wealth") is a dirty word But the Torah seeks to limit inequality by redistributing wealth in a variety of ways.
For example, the Torah mandates a primitive form of welfare: "You shall not pick the undeveloped twigs of your vineyard and the fallen fruit of your vineyard you shall not gather; for the poor and the prosleyte shall you leave them." (Leviticus 19:10). Leviticus also sought to limit inequality by mandating redistribution of land every 50 (25:28).
Having said that, the Torah is more liberal than radical, because it does contemplate significant material inequality: if an all-powerful government was capable of eliminating poverty, there would be no poor to pick up the "fallen fruit" referred to in Leviticus 19:10. In other words, the Torah contemplates a pre-industrial version of the modern welfare state, which limits, but does not eliminate, inequality.
In sum, the author of the Torah (whether singular or plural, whether human or divine) would probably not fit well into either the modern left or the modern right.
Of course, all of this discussion may beg one huge question: so what?
Should we vote the way we think the Torahs author(s) would? The appropriate answer requires us to think about the proper relationship between faith and politics. The Torahs rules, whether divinely written or not, were written for Jews. To what extent should these rules govern a religiously diverse society?
Jewish law cannot govern a secular society but our politics must be informed by our values, and those values should be at least somewhat affected by Torah and tradition. I don't give the past a veto over my political views - but I do give it a voice.

JERUSALEM THE WALKABLE (9-6-02)
Most Americans think of Jerusalem as a spiritual center or as Israels capital. But this city of about 650,000 people is also a city where apolitical people work and play, and where transportation and urban form matter as much as in Atlanta or Memphis or Baltimore.
After a little exploring on a trip last month, I noticed that most of Jerusalem does not resemble any neighborhood in Atlanta.
Atlanta is dominated by two types of areas: sterile skyscraper districts (in downtown, parts of Midtown, and parts of Buckhead) and low-density, auto-oriented areas dominated by single family houses; intown areas differ from suburbs primarily in house and lot size.
But most of Jerusalem falls into neither category. Jerusalem has more than 13,000 people per square mile, some four times as many as Atlanta and more than seven times as many as Alpharetta, Yet I saw almost no high-rises.
How does Jerusalem do it? Most of Jerusalem is dominated by row after row of apartment buildings of two to four stories, making it compact enough for Jerusalemites to walk to shops and synagogues, yet low-slung enough to avoid the claustrophia some feel in downtown Atlanta or midtown Manhattan.
In other words, a walk through Jerusalem shows that "density" doesnt have to be a dirty word even for skyscraper-phobes.
But density alone is not enough for walkability. Even in dense parts of Atlanta ([like parts of] Midtown and Buckhead), city streets are often so wide that pedestrians cannot comfortably cross them. By contrast, Jerusalems streets are narrow enough to be comfortably crossed in a few seconds: I never saw a city street with more than four (usually narrow) lanes.
In other words, Jerusalem teaches us that skinny streets are walkable streets. And some Jerusalem neighborhoods do almost nothing to accommodate the automobile.
For example, the Jewish Quarter within the Old City is essentially a giant pedestrian mall. In many of its residential streets, there is no need for sidewalks not because everyone drives everywhere, but because the streets are too narrow, and the pedestrians too numerous, to accommodate any significant number of vehicles.
So rather than going into the heart of the Old City, taxis and buses stop at its outskirts. The Quarter is centered around a square, and numerous streets shoot off the square in every direction.
Each of these streets, in turn, is flanked by courtyards surrounded by apartments; some Jewish Quarter residents live in walkups, while others have apartments with private entrances directly accessible from the street.
More modern neighborhoods, of course, do more to accommodate cars. In parts of Southwest Jerusalem built in the 1920s and 1930s, there are plenty of cars, but off-street parking lots are invisible or nonexistent. Instead, cars are parked on the street enhancing safety by creating a buffer between pedestrians and speeding cars, and making streets less deserted by bringing drivers to the street instead of segregating them in the huge, ugly parking lots that infest most of Atlanta.
Southwest Jerusalem residents get shade from street trees plenty of trees in some blocks, too few in others. Because the trees tend to be new and small, much of Jerusalem is far less lush than Atlantas greener neighborhoods.
Of course, Jerusalem is not Utopia, even leaving aside terrorism, and dehyradating summer heat. Nearly every building I saw in Jerusalem was brown and made of stone, apparently because of a municipal ordinance enacted to give "a certain romantic quality to the buildings" according to an Israeli Ministry of Foreign Affairs web page.
Personally, I found the pervasive "brown-ness" of Jerusalem to be monotonous and even disorienting, making it hard to distinguish one part of Jerusalem from another especially since I had spent the previous week in the historic areas of Buffalo, N.Y., where the citys Victorian neighborhoods are a riot of blues and purples and greens.
Then again, everyone has their own tastes in such matters.
Israels transportation policies, unlike Jerusalems architecture and street design, should be familiar to any Atlantan. During the past several decades, metro Atlantas city and county governments have followed a self-contradictory transportation policy: On one hand, our politicians built MARTA and other public transit systems to facilitate access to the city center and increase mobility. But they also emasculated MARTA by building highways such as I-285 and Georgia 400, dispensing people and jobs to places without MARTA service, forcing them drive more and to choke the roads with cars and pollutants.
Similarly, Jerusalem is building a light rail system, one likely to be far more succesful than Atlantas, because the citys high density means many more people can walk to stations than in Atlanta). But the national government is busy sabotaging the rail system by building the Trans-Israel Highway, a billion-dollar road that may well disperse development to now-unsettled areas.
On balance, Atlantans can learn a lot about street design from Jerusalem but I only wish Israelis would learn from Atlantas mistakes.

WHAT TO DO ABOUT THE BLACK-JEWISH "ALLIANCE" (8-9-02)
On Aug. 20, one election may be of special interest to local Jews: the Democratic primary in Georgias 4th District between incumbent Cynthia McKinney and challenger Denise Majette. Most Jews will probably support Majette, because of McKinneys pro-Palestinian stands and because her support for Israel has been less than enthusiastic. (For example, earlier this year McKinney refused to vote for a pro-Israel resolution that passed the House 352-21).
Although both McKinney and Majette are black, their contest has placed Jews on the opposite side of the fence from much of the black political Establishment
In such situations, the press typically teems with reports about the "broken black-Jewish alliance". Yet when Jimmy Carter wrote an op-ed in the New York Times that many people considered anti-Israel, there was little discussion of the "broken Southern Baptist-Jewish alliance" .
In fact, the black-Jewish alliance is about as real as the Southern Baptist-Jewish Alliance --which is to say, not very real at all.
Fifty or 60 years ago, our grandparents could talk about a black-Jewish alliance with a straight face, because Jews and blacks lived in the same urban neighborhoods and were discriminated against by the same people -- white Christians who didnt want either group in their schools or neighborhoods.
But these common interests have evaporated during the last several decades. While blacks still suffer disproportionately from racism and poverty, Jews generally get along well in America maybe even too well given the skyrocketing intermarriage rates of the past several decades.
Nor are Jews and blacks united by geography anymore, because our desire to move to overwhelmingly white neighborhoods is just as strong as that of non-Jews.
For example, Atlantas south side long majority blackcontains few Jews. And the only synagogue south of I-20 will soon be built in overwhelmingly white Fayette County, many miles to the south of most of Atlantas black neighborhoods.
Still, Atlanta is more integrated than some other large urban regions. For example, Clevelands most heavily Jewish suburb, Beachwood, is less than 10% black, and more integrated suburbs like Cleveland Heights have been losing Jews in recent decades.
To sum up, all that blacks and Jews have in common is that -- before I was born both groups were oppressed by white Christians, a slender peg on which to hang an alliance.
Given that Jews and blacks have no special reason to be allies, how should we interact with each other? What do we owe each other?
I begin with the simple, widely held moral assumption that color blindness is ordinarily a good thing, so it logically follows that Jews should treat black Christians the same way we treat white Christians.
That means that we cannot expect blacks to fight for Jews special interests any more than we expect other whites to be our natural allies and that we should be no more disappointed by blacks failure to follow our lead than by whites failure to do so.
And because we cannot reasonably expect blacks to behave differently from white non-Jews, we should resist the temptation to blame blacks for the anti-Semitism of a Louis Farrakhan or to assume that his remarks represent the views of most blacks.
Just as Jews owe blacks the same treatment they owe other non-Jews, blacks owe Jews the same treatment they owe other non-blacks.
Blacks cannot expect us to be consistently supportive of policies they support any more than they should expect white Presbyterians or Baptists to endorse that agenda.
On the other hand, blacks have a right to expect just as much civility and decency from Jews as they should expect from white Presbyterians or Baptists.
In sum, in matters of politics Jews should see blacks simply as non-Jews and blacks should see Jews simply as whites.
Once both groups adjust their expectations accordingly, black-Jewish relations may well improve.
(Editing note: I personally would have used the term "non-Jewish blacks" instead of "blacks", since there are a few Jewish blacks out there. But this sort of judgment call is what editors are for).

TORAH LESSONS FOR ATLANTA'S SUBURBS (7-19-02)

In order to limit suburban sprawl and preserve natural resources, Oregon requires municipal governments to establish "urban growth boundaries" around cities and inner suburbs. Outside the boundary, subdivisions are prohibited -- and agriculture and forests are promoted.
In other words, Portland and other Oregon cities cannot sprawl indiscriminately into the countryside as Atlanta suburbs have; instead, Portland is surrounded by a green belt of rural land.
Some results of Portland's growth boundaries are miraculous; in the past two decades, the city of Portland's population has increased by 40 percent -- as fast as [that of] its suburbs. By contrast, the city of Atlanta's population increased at a sluggish 5 percent pace during the 1990s, while its suburbs exploded.
Nevertheless, Oregon's policies are not likely to be adopted by Georgia (or other states) - partially because of concerns about Portland's ever-increasing home prices, but also because of a widely held view that any environmental regulation of real estate violates developers' "property rights" to unlimited profits.
For example, John Charles of the libertarian Cascade Policy Institute says Oregon's growth boundary "strips thousands of property owners of a reasonable use of their property" by prohibiting subdivisions and office buildings in agricultural zones.
The Supreme Court has ruled that regulation is subject to a balancing test -- [a] landowner's loss is balanced against [the] public interest favoring regulation. So protecting natural resources is subject to judicial whim.
By contrast, the Torah takes a clear pro-regulation position - one with lessons for the unbridled growth in Atlanta.
For example, Numbers 35:2-5 states that upon entering Israel, the Hebrew people had to assign "towns for the Levites to dwell in [and] . . . pasture around their towns." That town pasture "shall extend a thousand cubits around the town wall all around. You shall measure off 2,000 cubits outside the town . . . with the town in the center."
The medieval Torah commentator Rashi explained that the inner 1,000 cubits (about 500 yards) surrounding cities were to be undeveloped, and the outer 1,000 were for agriculture.
In other words, the Torah created the first urban growth boundary. The Levite tribe -- to a greater extent than modern-day Oregonians -- was limited to the urban core, while the suburbs were reserved for flora and fauna and could only spread out over 2,000 cubits.
The Torah also orders farmers to let the earth lie unplowed every seventh year (Leviticus 25:1-6) and provides that agricultural land must be returned to [its] original owners every 50 years to limit inequalities of wealth (Leviticus 25:10).
Post-Biblical Jewish law extended the goals of land use regulation by enacting early forms of environmental regulation.
For example, Bab Batra (a book of the Mishnah, a code of Jewish law written around 200) creates a zoning code limiting the location of cisterns, ditches, caves, seeds, dovecotes, bakeries, graves, tanneries and other potentially noxious sites.
Tanneries [for example] create foul odors, so the rabbis were creating an early form of environmental regulation. Dovecotes had to be 50 cubits away from villages because doves might eat crops.
The position of Jewish law is clear: A property owner's right to develop must sometimes yield to the broader good, including keeping rural land rural and limiting pollution.
Think of that the next time you drive up I-85.

WHEN "PREDICT AND PROVIDE" DOESN'T WORK by Michael Lewyn (6-7-02)

A few weeks ago, an article ran in the Jewish Times about the growth of suburban synagogues. One interviewee said: "You dont keep building in places where the Jews used to live. You try to figure out where theyre going to live." In other words, predict where people are going to live, and provide services for them.
During the past few decades, this "predict and provide" model has been used to justify disinvestment in older Atlanta neighborhoods, and to justify shifting Jewish facilities to outer suburbs far from the regions historic core. (I hasten to add that the interviewee in question may not have meant to endorse such disinvestment).
For example, a Jewish retirement home moved to Alpharetta because, according to its executive director, Alpharetta is "up-and-coming" even though in fact (according to a related Jewish Times story) "only a few of the homes residents have relatives in Alpharetta."
So whats wrong with predicting and providing? First of all, the "predict and provide" model is, to some extent a self-fulfilling prophecy. If you build something (say, a Jewish day school, or a Jewish community center, or a synagogue) in place X, committed Jews are likely, other factors being equal, to move to place X.
For example, as Beth Jacob in Toco Hills began to prosper, Jews started to move to Toco Hills, which in turn caused other Jewish-oriented enterprises to move to Toco Hills.
Would this cycle of Jewish migration have happened if Beth Jacob did not exist? Of course not. Toco Hills would be just another nondescript older suburb, with as much of a Jewish presence as East Point or College Park.
To be sure, broader demographic trends have brought Jews -- especially Jews who are less affluent, less committed or both -- to move to Christian-dominated areas. For example, the quest of middle-class families for cheap real estate has scattered Jews to Cobb and Gwinnett Counties.
But even there [in suburbia], the Jewish elites investment patterns have an impact. Because the regions major Jewish community Center is in Dunwoody and its day schools are mostly in Sandy Springs and Dunwoody, Jewish families who cant afford to live in those ritzy suburbs are more likely to live in nearby northern outer suburbs than in cheaper, newly gentrifying intown neighborhoods such as East Atlanta.
Sometimes the "predict and provide" model fails on its own terms: Attempts to predict the Jewish future often just plain dont work. For example, in 1964 Look Magazine ran a cover story on "The Vanishing American Jew." Today, American Jews still exist and Look Magazine has vanished.
Even within Judaism, all manner of predictions have gone into the ash heap of history. For example, the 19th-century architect of American Reform Judaism, Rabbi Isaac Mayer Wise, called his prayer book Minhag America (in English, "custom of America"); evidently, he believed that Reform Judaism would become the "custom of America."
Instead, Orthodox Judaism (as well as in-between alternatives to both Orthodoxy and Reform) thrived in the 20th century.
Similarly, attempts to predict where Atlantas Jews will live have occasionally misfired. A decade ago, the conventional wisdom was that intown Atlanta is dying. By the end of the 20th century, it was predicted [a casual reader of the Jewish press might have believed that], Atlanta would look like Cleveland, which has only one synagogue within the city limits and where synagogues in the inner suburbs are dying as the population moves further out into the exurban wilderness.
But instead, the old-line intown shuls and the middle-aged inner-suburban shuls have been joined by newcomers: the Virginia Highlands/Morningside area boasts two older synagogues, [and also] Chabad Intown and Shomrei Shamayim. Similarly, Toco Hillss Beth Jacob has been joined by Young Israel and two small Sephardic synagogues, while two small Reconstructionist congregations are taking root a few miles away.
Are older intown synagogues losing members? Perhaps but if so, the lost members are moving not just to suburbia but also to smaller, more intimate intown congregations.
In other words, any attempt by our communitys leaders to predict and provide for future Jewish migration is a self-fulfilling prophecy when it succeeds and just plain wasteful when it fails. Either way, whats the point?

IF I WERE A RICH MAN: THE INTOWN SOLUTION (5-3-02)

Atlantas Jewish billionaires Arthur Blank and Bernie Marcus have made headlines by spending money on a football team [,]and an aquarium and Atlantas Jews have responded by inflicting their unsolicited opinions on each other.
Some argue that Jewish tycoons should spend less money on secular toys and more money on Jewish causes, while others point out that the same tycoons have already done plenty for their coreligionists.
These arguments caused me to ask myself: What would I do if I was very rich rich enough not just to write checks to other peoples good causes, but to start my own good cause? (It goes without saying, of course, that any billionaires reading this article should do whatever I would do).
My unique good cause would combine my religious interests with my major secular interest the promotion of good urbanism, by which I mean places that cater to people as well as cars.
I believe that tomorrows children should not grow up as prisoners of mommys car, but instead should have the opportunity to live in places where they can walk, bike or take the bus to synagogues, stores, community centers and the rest of the world outside their backyards. That means neighborhoods where sidewalk-lined residential streets are within walking distance of civic amenities and where neighborhoods are connected by bus routes.
But all too often, families have to choose between Jewish life and neighborhood livability. Most of Atlantas Jewish day schools and community centers have moved to suburbs where children are condemned to a state of infantile dependence on their parents cars until they turn 16. Then they suddenly (according to Georgia laws) become mature enough to create havoc on the highways. My ideal charity would end this problem by bringing major community facilities to pedestrian- and transit-friendly communities (most of which are in intown neighborhoods).
The most commonly discussed solution for the Jewish communitys failure to adequately serve intown residents is a Jewish community center (JCC) certainly a worthy cause. But were I a community-oriented billionaire, a JCC alone would not be my first choice for two reasons.
First, a familys housing choices are more likely to be based on the desirability of the nearest school than on the proximity of a place to work out or play ball (to name a few of our JCCs many worthy activities).
Second, I suspect that a Jewish day school education does more for a childs Jewish identity and level of Jewish learning than proximity to a JCC.
So I would spend my money on heavily subsidized Jewish day schools in the sort of places I would like my children (if I had any) to experience in walkable, transit-friendly neighborhoods (such as the Virginia Highlands-Morningside area) or near MARTA stations.
A few more Jewish day schools would not only promote Jewish continuity but also make intown life a viable option for families who have been scared into the suburbs by Atlantas public schools.
In addition, my schools would be far more successful in attracting students than suburban day schools. Because suburbs such as Alpharetta already have highly reputed, taxpayer-subsidized public schools, only
The most Jewishly committed parents there are willing to forego the primary benefit of suburbia (its "good schools") by spending thousands of dollars on private Jewish schools.
By contrast, the low prestige of Atlantas public schools means that intown parents are a captive audience: an intown Jewish school might attract the majority of Jewish city children instead of a tiny share of suburban children.
Some philanthropists have apparently followed my advice by giving Torah Day School enough money to move to the heart of Toco Hills thus giving Atlantas Orthodox parents an intown alternative. Now all we need is a zillionaire who would do the same for the rest of Atlantas Jewish families.

TORAH, TRADITION AND THE NORTHERN ARC PROPOSAL (2-21-02)

Gov. Barnes wants to spend $2.4 billion in taxpayers money to build the Northern Arc, a highway that would span Cherokee County, Forsyth County and other areas far from the Perimeter.
Why could such a dry, technical issue have to do with Jewish values? Plenty.
For more than 3,000 years, Jewish tradition has condemned those who sought to impoverish the needy and disabled. Leviticus 19:14 states: "You shall not curse the deaf, and you shall not put a stumbling block before the blind" words that, read literally, condemn mistreatment of the disabled.
In the very next verse, the Torah urges government officials not to favor the rich over the poor, asserting: "Ye shall do no unrighteousness in judgment; thou shalt not respect the person of the poor, nor favor the person of the mighty" (Leviticus 19:15).
Centuries later, Maimonides instructed us how to help the needy, writing: "The highest degree [of charity] is that of a person who assists a poor Jew . . . by putting him in a position where he can dispense with other peoples aid."
But throughout the 20th century Georgias transportation policies made the poor and disabled more dependent on charity and welfare. By building highways like I-75, I-85 and I-285, the state has made it convenient for businesses to abandon Atlanta in favor of its suburbs. And because these suburbs often have minimal or nonexistent public transit, nondrivers have no access to the jobs the state enticed into suburbia.
While government has built a 24-hour highway system to serve drivers, the majority of metro Atlanta jobs are not within walking distance of a bus stop. And according to the Atlanta Regional Commission, only 34 percent of the regions jobs were within a one-hour public transit ride for low-income Atlantans in 2000.
Furthermore, contrary to popular myth, there are plenty of transit-dependent Atlantans: In the city of Atlanta (hardly one of Americas most transit-friendly places) 28 percent of households and more than a third of African-American households had no car in 1990 according to Census figures.
The Northern Arc will worsen the mismatch between low-income workers and jobs.
Supporters of the road which would link I-75 and I-85admit that they support the highway because it will encourage businesses to move from Atlanta and older suburbs such as Sandy Springs and Dunwoody to Cherokee and Forsyth Counties.
For example, Cherokee County J.J. Biello states that the highway will "attract industry and jobs" to the county. (Conversely, the Forsyth County Commission voted 4-1 in favor of a resolution opposing the Arc because members fear the development that Biello welcomes).
Cherokee and Forsyth Counties have no public bus service whatseoever. That means the Northern Arc would increase the number of jobs that are unreachable by the carless, who are usually urban, poor or disabled.
So if the state builds the Northern Arc, it will do exactly the opposite of what Jewish tradition recommends. Torah and tradition command us to employ the poor, but the Northern Arc will freeze nondrivers out of the labor market, and thus force onto the welfare rolls those Atlantans too poor to buy cars or too disabled to drive.
Jews should oppose auto-oriented transportation policies for a more selfish reason: More jobs moving to places like Forsyth County means more driving, which means consumption of oil, which means more revenue for Arab oil producers, which means more money going to Israels enemies in Saudi Arabia and Iran.
To put the matter crudely, a vote for the Northern Arc is a vote for the bankers of Hezbollah and Yasir Arafat. The most common argument for the Northern Arc is that it will relieve traffic congestion. But like criminals trying to hide their misdeeds, the Arcs backers cannot keep their story straight.
On the one hand, Arc proponents claim that it will unclog traffic a claim disproved by the fact that metro Atlantas most congested streets are in the city and its inner suburbs, far from the proposed route of the Northern Arc.
On the other hand, Arc backers claim that it will bring jobs to outside-the-Perimeter counties. But if employers move to Cherokee and Forsyth Counties, those counties will have more people on the roads which means more cars and more traffic congestion, not less. Thus, the claim that the Northern Arc will reduce congestion is simply rubbish.
So if you believe that work is better than welfare and that the state doesn't need to export inside-the-Perimeter congestion to places like bucolic Forsyth County, you should write Gov. Barnes and the other gubernatorial candidates, your county commissioners and your legislators telling them that Georgia can find better places to spend $2.4 billion. To learn more about how to fight the Northern Arc, contact the Sierra Club at (404) 607-1262.

SUBURBAN SPRAWL AND JEWISH DISCONTINUITY (4-7-00)

Over the past few decades, metropolitan Atlanta, like the rest of America, has been transformed by "suburban sprawl" -- the movement of middle-class families and jobs from older urban cores to newer, more automobile-dependent suburbs. Between 1970 and 1998, the city of Atlanta's population declined from 495,000 to 403,000, while its suburbs mushroomed.
And over the past several decades, the area's Jewish population has moved outward along with the rest of the population: first from its traditional south Atlanta core to north Atlanta neighborhoods such as Morningside, and more recently to a variety of suburbs.
This migration away from the central city has had a serious negative effect on the city itself, of course, by removing an educationally accomplished and economically vibrant set of residents and potential leaders. The movement was part of a larger [trend of] "white flight" that has been well-documented and analyzed.
Less well-understood is the impact that this migration has had on the Jewish community itself. What is now becoming clear is that the dispersal out of the core city neighborhoods has frayed the bonds of acquaintance and friendship that had made a Jewish community coherent and strong and thereby contributed to the increasingly severe problems we face with continuity and identity.
The shift in Atlanta is less pronounced than in Rust Belt cities like Cleveland and St. Louis. In each of those cities, only one synagogue remains within the city limits, and even the inner suburbs -- [the ones] closest to the downtown and most walkable -- like Cleveland's Cleveland Heights and St. Louis's University City [--] are losing people to outer suburbs. For example, only 28 percent of Cleveland-area Jewish households now live in the traditionally Jewish inner suburbs of Cleveland Heights, Shaker Heights, and University Heights.
In 1996, one Conservative rabbi whose congregation voted to leave Cleveland Heights for an outer suburb described the neighborhood it was abandoning as "dying."
At the same time that the nationwide migration to suburbia was happening, the Jewish community was losing its continuity through intermarriage.
In 1912, less than 3.5 percent of American-born Jews married non-Jews. In 1968 (the heyday of the Jewish inner suburb) Albert Vorspan, director of the Union of American Hebrew Congregations' Commission on Social Action, wrote that "many more Jews are marrying out of the faith than anybody had realized" because between 20 and 30 percent of Jews married non-Jews. Today, 40 percent or more of Jews (depending on whose survey you believe) "marry out."
Are urban decay and Jewish decay linked, or is this correlation a mere coincidence. Common sense suggests that suburban sprawl and intermarriage do in fact go together.
During the first half of the century, most Jewish children, no matter what their parents' theology, grew up in heavily Jewish urban enclaves where they walked everywhere and were thus in constant contact with their Jewish neighbors. In such an environment, it was relatively easy for young Jews to grow up with, and later to love and marry, their co-religionists.
By contrast, many of today's young Jews, especially in Atlanta, grew up in areas totally dominated by the automobile. I grew up in an area where the nearest regular MARTA bus stop was a mile away. I couldn't safely walk to the bus stop or to a neighbor's house because there were no sidewalks and the neighbors' trees and shrubs went right up to the curb, preventing me from walking on the grass as one can in many sidewalk-less Midwestern suburbs -- or in Toco Hills near Beth Jacob.
Even if a Jewish family's neighbors are disproportionately Jewish -- itself an unlikely event outside chasidic or Orthodox circles where residents walk to synagogue as a matter of religious duty -- most young Jews do not see their neighbors particularly often in unwalkable outer suburbs.
Historically, familiarity was the precursor to romance. Now in our dispersed suburban lives, the ties to Jewish neighbors have been weakened. One result: a rise in intermarriage.
Admittedly, it is possible for Jewish parents -- or their children, after they reach driving age -- to drive outside the neighborhood to socialize with other Jews. But this requires a level of commitment that, in practice, deters all but the least motivated. By contrast, Jews who grow up in a walkable ethnic enclave, such as Pittsburgh's Squirrel Hill, need not make such an effort; instead, they will meet other Jews as a matter of course.
There is little statistical evidence one way or the other as to whether suburbanites are more likely to intermarry or abandon Judaism. However, it does seem clear that city dwellers are more likely to identify with Judaism.
The book "Jews on the Move" by Sidney and Alice Goldstein, divided Jews into "core Jews" -- Jews who practice Judaism or at least regard themselves as Jewish -- and the "peripheral population" -- non-Jews of Jewish ancestry. In 1990, 51 percent of the "core Jews" but only 41 percent of the "peripheral population" lived in central cities.
Similarly, city dwellers are more likely to be observant. For example, 15 of Illinois's Orthodox congregations, but only 8 of the state's Reform congregations, are located in central cities . . . [NOTE: I am using ellipses to delete a sentence that turned out to be not quite right; I said there was a similar gap in Atlanta, because I thought a couple of Orthodox shuls were within the city limits which are in fact just a few blocks outside).
This may be so because intown living is more compatible with the mitzvah of walking to a synagogue. By contrast, I have seen Reform synagogues in sidewalk-less areas where it was physically impossible to walk on the street without endangering one's life.
What can we do to break the pattern of linked urban decay and Jewish decay?
As individuals, we can oppose government policies that accelerate suburban sprawl, like the billion-dollar highways that shift development outside the Perimeter or the zoning decisions that encourage ever-lower residential density. We can also support public and private spending that hastens the renewal of walkable city neighborhoods.
As a community, we can also contribute to our continuity by putting more of our dollars inside the city, building a Jewish infrastructure in the city and in walkable suburbs like Decatur that makes it more comfortable for Jews to stay in town.
Now, for example, most of our Jewish day schools are in the suburbs, where they must compete with high-quality public schools that were the primary factor in luring parents to live in the suburbs. With good schools close by and already supported by required taxes, only the richest or most motivated parents are likely to send their children to a Jewish school.
By contrast, a day school or two in the city of Atlanta, like Christian religious schools in most American cities, would benefit from a "captive audience" of Jews who want to stay in the city but will not send their children to Atlanta's public schools with their records of generally inferior academic accomplishment. As the new community high school searches for a permanent home, it should consider how it might help continuity by looking inside the city limits.
It is too late to rebuilt the demolished community center in Midtown or to unbuild the expanded center at Zaban Park. But it is not too late to explore a small satellite JCC facility to serve the continuing recreational needs of the intown community.
Divesting in the city has come at the price of a weaker communal identity. Reinvesting in neighborhoods where our children can truly grow up together could pay a rich dividend of a strengthened Jewish future for them -- and for us.

Posted by lewyn at 2:40 PM EST
Updated: Monday, 27 December 2004 2:44 PM EST
Introducing myself
I am a wandering law professor- this year visiting at Southern Illinois University in Carbondale, IL, not sure yet where I will be next year. The purpose of this blog is to post my old articles and to post misc. thoughts of mine on major and minor issues of the day.

Posted by lewyn at 2:31 PM EST

Newer | Latest | Older